Preview Extract
Chapter 2
The Measurement and Structure
of the National Economy
n
Learning Objectives
I.
Section Goals
A. Differentiate among the three approaches to national income accounting (Sec. 2.1)
B. Explain how GDP is measured (Sec. 2.2)
C. Discuss the measurement of aggregate saving and its relation to wealth (Sec. 2.3)
D. Explain the calculations of real GDP, price indexes, and inflation (Sec. 2.4)
E. Define real and nominal interest rates (Sec. 2.5)
II.
Notes to Ninth Edition Users
A. In the In Touch box on the National Income and Product Accounts, we added more description
of how often the data are revised.
B. In Section 2.4, we added some details on how GDP growth rates are calculated, in terms of
quarterly data at annualized growth rates. We also added a discussion of seasonal adjustment of
data. Finally, we added a graph showing the annual quarterly GDP growth rate.
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
Chapter 2 The Measurement and Structure of the National Economy
n
Teaching Notes
I.
National Income Accounting: The Measurement of Production, Income, and Expenditure
(Sec. 2.1)
A. National income accounts: an accounting framework used in measuring current economic
activity
B. Three alternative approaches give the same measurements
1. Product approach: the amount of output produced
2. Income approach: the incomes generated by production
3. Expenditure approach: the amount of spending by purchasers
C. Juice business example shows that all three approaches are equal
17
1. Important concept in product approach: value added = value of output minus value of inputs
purchased from other producers
D. Why are the three approaches equivalent?
1. They must be, by definition
2. Any output produced (product approach) is purchased by someone (expenditure approach)
and results in income to someone (income approach)
3. The fundamental identity of national income accounting:
total production = total income = total expenditure
(2.1)
II. Gross Domestic Product (Sec. 2.2)
A. The product approach to measuring GDP
1. GDP (gross domestic product) is the market value of final goods and services newly
produced within a nation during a fixed period of time
Data Application
The period referred to here is either a quarter or a year. You may want to show students what
some of the tables from the National Income and Product Accounts, most easily accessible on the
Internet at www.bea.gov.
Students are also interested in seeing what happens in the financial markets and to public opinion
on the day a new GDP report comes out.
2. Market value: allows adding together unlike items by valuing them at their market prices
a. Problem: misses nonmarket items such as homemaking, the value of environmental
quality, and natural resource depletion
Analytical Problems 1 and 3 both discuss difficulties in counting nonmarket items for GDP,
including the important idea that GDP is not the same as welfare.
b. There is some adjustment to reflect the underground economy
c. Government services (that arenโt sold in markets) are valued at their cost of production
3. Newly produced: counts only things produced in the given period; excludes things produced
earlier
4. Final goods and services
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
18
Abel/Bernanke/Croushore โข Macroeconomics, Tenth Edition
a. Donโt count intermediate goods and services (those used up in the production of other
goods and services in the same period that they themselves were produced)
b. Final goods & services are those that are not intermediate
c. Capital goods (goods used to produce other goods) are final goods since they arenโt used
up in the same period that they are produced
d. Inventory investment (the amount that inventories of unsold finished goods, goods
in process, and raw materials have changed during the period) is also treated as a final
good
e. Adding up value added works well, since it automatically excludes intermediate goods
5. GNP vs. GDP
a. GNP (gross national product) = output produced by domestically owned factors
of production
GDP = output produced within a nation
b. GDP = GNP – NFP (net factor payments from abroad)
(2.2)
c. NFP = payments to domestically owned factors located abroad minus payments
to foreign factors located domestically
Data Application
Prior to December 1991, the United States used GNP as its main measure of production; after
that, GDP became the main concept. The main reasons for the switch were that GDP is more
relevant to production in an open economy (though GNP is more relevant for income), and GDP
is more precise than GNP in the advance estimate, since net factor payments are difficult to
measure quickly. See Survey of Current Business, November 1991, for a discussion of the switch.
d. Example: Engineering revenues for a road built by a U.S. company in Saudi Arabia is
part of U.S. GNP (built by a U.S. factor of production), not U.S. GDP, and is part of
Saudi GDP (built in Saudi Arabia), not Saudi GNP
e. Difference between GNP and GDP is small for the United States, about 0.2%, but higher
for countries that have many citizens working abroad
Data Application
The timeline for national income and product account releases is generally:
Advance estimate
Last week of month following end of quarter
Second estimate
Last week of second following month
Third estimate
Last week of third following month
Revisions occur every July for the following three years. Each new release contains either
additional new data that was not available before, or a change in seasonal factors, or a correction
of errors made previously. Periodically, the annual revision in July contains significant changes in
the method used to produce the data; these revisions can dramatically change the data going far
back in time. [Note: This structure is different now than it was before: Prior to 2009, the first three
releases were known as advance, preliminary, and final, and major changes in the methods used to
create the data were saved up for a benchmark revision, which took place about every 5 years,
instead of being incorporated into the annual release.]
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
Chapter 2 The Measurement and Structure of the National Economy
19
B. The expenditure approach to measuring GDP
1. Measures total spending on final goods and services produced within a nation during a
specified period of time
2. Four main categories of spending: consumption (C), investment (I ), government purchases
of goods and services (G), and net exports (NX)
3. Y = C + I + G + NX, the incomeโexpenditure identity
(2.3)
4. Consumption: spending by domestic households on final goods and services
(including those produced abroad)
a. About 2/3 of U.S. GDP
b. Three categories
(1) Consumer durables (examples: cars, TV sets, furniture, and major appliances)
(2) Nondurable goods (examples: food, clothing, fuel)
(3) Services (examples: education, health care, financial services, and transportation)
Data Application
Note that the consumption category in the national income and product accounts does not
correspond to economistsโ concept of consumption, because it includes the full value of durable
goods. When economists study consumption behavior, they must account for this; one way to do
so is to assume that durable goods provide services that are proportional to their existing stock.
Total consumption is this fraction of the stock of consumer durables, plus nondurables and services.
5. Investment: spending for new capital goods (fixed investment) plus inventory investment
a. Volatile, with fixed investment about 13% to 20% of U.S. GDP
b. Business (or nonresidential) fixed investment: spending by businesses on structures,
equipment, and intellectual property products, such as software, research and
development, or artistic originals
c. Residential fixed investment: spending on the construction of houses and apartment
buildings
d. Inventory investment: increases in firmsโ inventory holdings
Data Application
A major change in the National Income and Product Accounts came in July 2013, when the
accounts were changed to include intellectual property products, which are treated as capital. Until
then, artwork, such as movies, was treated as adding to GDP only in the year it was created. But
much artwork continues to have value long after it was created, so it makes sense to treat it as
capital. As a result of this change, real GDP and investment were revised up significantly.
6. Government purchases of goods and services: spending by the government on goods or
services
a. About 1/6 of U.S. GDP
b. Most by state and local governments, not federal government
c. Not all government expenditures are purchases of goods and services
(1) Some are payments that are not made in exchange for current goods and services
(2) One type is transfers, including Social Security payments, welfare, and
unemployment benefits
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
20
Abel/Bernanke/Croushore โข Macroeconomics, Tenth Edition
(3) Another type is interest payments on the government debt
d. Some government spending is for capital goods that add to the nationโs capital stock, such
as highways, airports, bridges, and water and sewer systems
Data Application
People often donโt realize how large transfer programs are relative to federal government
consumption expenditures. For example, in 2017, transfer payments were $2.7 trillion,
while government consumption expenditures were only $1.0 trillion. Gross investment by the
federal government ($0.3 trillion) was about the same as depreciation ($0.3 trillion), so net
investment was close to zero.
7. Net exports: exports minus imports
a. Exports: goods produced in the country that are purchased by foreigners
b. Imports: goods produced abroad that are purchased by residents in the country
c. Imports are subtracted from GDP, as they represent goods produced abroad, and were
included in consumption, investment, and government purchases
Data Application
Behind the scenes at the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), a major change took place in the
2000s concerning the national income accounts and the data on GDP. Because the types of goods
and services people buy changed so much over time, the BEA decided to modify how it
categorizes industries when it collects data on production. The new system was known as NAICS:
the North American Industry Classification System; it replaced a system called SIC: Standard
Industrial Classification. NAICS differs from SIC in both principle and in practice.
The key principle governing NAICS is that firms that use similar production processes will be
classified in the same industry, which was not true under SIC. The result is that the number of
firms in different industries changed; for example, the manufacturing industry is different under
NAICS than under SIC.
One of the main reasons for the switch from SIC to NAICS is the growth of service industries
and computer-related industries. In the previous 70 years, manufacturing output had declined
from 54% of GDP to 38%, while the output of service industries had increased from 35% of GDP
to 54%. The SIC had not been updated to reflect the changes in the economy. NAICS improved
the compatibility of U.S. statistics with those in other countries.
The disadvantage of the switch from SIC to NAICS is that data from today based on NAICS is
not strictly comparable to data from the past based on SIC. But the BEA believed that the
improved quality of the data justified the loss of historical comparability. In addition, NAICS has
the advantage of being very adaptable when industries change; for example, its information sector
includes such categories as Internet publishing and broadcasting. Adding new categories will not
be difficult as technology changes further and new industries evolve.
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
Chapter 2 The Measurement and Structure of the National Economy
21
C. The income approach to measuring GDP
1. Adds up income generated by production (including profits and taxes paid to the
government)
a. National income = compensation of employees (including benefits) + proprietorsโ
income + rental income of persons + corporate profits + net interest + taxes on production
and imports + business current transfer payments + current surplus of government
enterprises
b. National income + statistical discrepancy = net national product
c. Net national product + depreciation (the value of capital that wears out in the period) =
gross national product (GNP)
d. GNP – net factor payments (NFP) = GDP
2. Private sector and government sector income
a. Private disposable income = income of the private sector = private sector income
earned at home (Y or GDP) and abroad (NFP) + payments from the government sector
(transfers, TR, and interest on government debt, INT) – taxes paid to government
private disposable income = Y + NFP + TR + INT – T
b. Governmentโs net income = taxes – transfers – interest payments = T – TR – INT
c. Private disposable income + governmentโs net income = GDP + NFP = GNP
(2.4)
(2.5)
Numerical Problems 1, 2, 3, 4, and 5 provide practice in working with the national income and
product accounts.
III. Saving and Wealth (Sec. 2.3)
A. Wealth
1. Household wealth = a householdโs assets minus its liabilities
2. National wealth = sum of all householdsโ, firmsโ, and governmentsโ wealth within the nation
3. Savings by individuals, businesses, and government determine wealth
B. Measures of aggregate saving
1. Saving = current income – current spending
2. Saving rate = saving/current income
3. Private saving = private disposable income – consumption
Spvt = (Y + NFP + TR + INT – T) – C
(2.6)
4. Government saving = net government income – government purchases of goods and services
Sgovt = (T – TR – INT) – G
(2.7)
a. Government saving = government budget surplus = government receipts – government
outlays
b. Government receipts = tax revenue (T)
c. Government outlays = government purchases of goods and services (G) + transfers (TR) +
interest payments on government debt (INT)
d. Government budget deficit = -Sgovt
e. Despite the BEAโs change in methods that explicitly recognize government investment,
the text simplifies matters by counting government investment as government purchases,
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
22
Abel/Bernanke/Croushore โข Macroeconomics, Tenth Edition
not investment. This avoids complications when the concepts are introduced and can be
modified for further analysis later.
5. National saving
a. National saving = private saving + government saving
b. S = Spvt + Sgovt
= [Y + NFP + TR + INT – C – T] + [T – TR – INT – G]
(2.8)
= Y + NFP – C – G = GNP – C – G
c. Text Fig. 2.1: plots national saving, private saving, and government saving relative to
GDP; note trend decline in ratio of national saving to GDP matches trend decline in
government saving relative to GDP
C. The uses of private saving
1. S = I + (NX + NFP)
S = I + CA
Derived from S = Y + NFP – C – G and Y = C + I + G + NX
CA = NX + NFP = current account balance
2. Spvt = I + (-Sgovt ) + CA
{using S = Spvt + Sgovt}
The uses-of-saving identityโsaving is used in three ways:
a. investment (I )
b. government budget deficit (-Sgovt)
c. current account balance (CA)
(2.9)
(2.10)
(2.11)
3. Text Fig. 2.2: shows uses-of-savings identity
a.
Private saving, gross private domestic investment, government budget deficit, and
current account balance, each as a percentage of GDP
b.
Since early 1990s, current account balance has been negative
c.
Foreigners buying U.S. assets
d.
In some crisis periods, we observe large increases in the government budget
deficit accompanied by sharp declines in gross private domestic investment and
increases in private saving
e.
In periods of strong growth, we observe a decline in private saving and the
government budget deficit, along with a rise in investment
Analytical Problem 4 has students examine how the uses-of-savings identity would change if we
redefined government saving so that government investment was separate from government
consumption expenditures, so that G = GCE + GI and Sgovt = (T – TR – INT ) – GCE.
D. Relating saving and wealth
1. Stocks and flows
a. Flow variables: measured per unit of time (GDP, income, saving, investment)
b. Stock variables: measured at a point in time (quantity of money, value of houses, capital stock)
c. Flow variables often equal rates of change of stock variables
2. Wealth and saving as stock and flow (wealth is a stock, saving is a flow)
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
Chapter 2 The Measurement and Structure of the National Economy
23
3. National wealth: domestic physical assets + net foreign assets
a. Countryโs domestic physical assets (capital goods and land)
b. Countryโs net foreign assets = foreign assets (foreign stocks, bonds, and capital goods
owned by domestic residents) minus foreign liabilities (domestic stocks, bonds, and
capital goods owned by foreigners)
c. Wealth matters because the economic well-being of a country depends on it
d. Changes in national wealth
(1) Change in value of existing assets and liabilities (change in price of financial assets,
or depreciation of capital goods)
(2) National saving (S = I + CA) raises wealth
e. Comparison of U.S. saving and investment with other countries
(1) The United States is a low-saving country; Japan is a high-saving country
(2) U.S. investment exceeds U.S. saving, so we have a negative current-account balance
IV. Real GDP, Price Indexes, and Inflation (Sec. 2.4)
A. Real GDP
1. Nominal variables are those in dollar terms
2. Problem: do changes in nominal values reflect changes in prices or quantities?
3. Real variables: adjust for price changes; reflect only quantity changes
4. Example of computers and bicycles
5. Nominal GDP is the dollar value of an economyโs final output measured at current market
prices
6. Real GDP is an estimate of the value of an economyโs final output, adjusting for changes
in the overall price level
7. Quarterly annualized growth rates of GDP are calculated using the formula
(2.12)
8. U.S. data are also generally seasonally adjusted
9. Text Figure 2.3 shows quarterly annualized U.S. GDP growth rates
Data Application
The first time that the national income and product accounts reported real GNP was in February
1959; prior to that time, inflation was usually so low that nominal GNP was all that it was thought
necessary to examine.
Numerical Problem 5 provides practice in calculating real and nominal GDP and price indexes
given several goods with different prices and quantities in two years.
B. Price Indexes
1. A price index measures the average level of prices for some specified set of goods and
services, relative to the prices in a specified base year
2. GDP deflator = 100 ยด nominal GDP/real GDP
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
24
Abel/Bernanke/Croushore โข Macroeconomics, Tenth Edition
Data Application
There are two price indexes available for consumption expenditures: the price index for personal
consumption expenditures (PCE) and the consumer price index (CPI). The PCE price index
provides a better measure of inflation for most purposes, which is why it is the main inflation
measure used by the Federal Reserve.
3. Note that base year P = 100
4. Consumer Price Index (CPI)
a. Monthly index of consumer prices; index averages 100 in reference base period
(1982 to 1984)
b. Based on basket of goods in expenditure base period, which is updated periodically
5. In Touch with Data and Research: The computer revolution and chain-weighted GDP
a. Choice of expenditure base period matters for GDP when prices and quantities of a good,
such as computers, are changing rapidly
b. BEA compromised by developing chain-weighted GDP
c. Now, however, components of real GDP donโt add up to real GDP, but discrepancy is
usually small
Data Application
Calculating chain-weighted indexes is not too hard and you can use the computer-bicycle
example in Table 2.4 in the textbook to illustrate how to do so. Define the Laspeyres quantity
index (using year 1 prices) for year 1 as the value of year 1 output at year 1 prices: L1 = $46,000;
the Laspeyres quantity index of year 2 output is L2 = $62,000. Define the Paasche quantity index
(using year 2 prices) for year 1 as the value of year 1 output at year 2 prices: P1 = $51,000; the Paasche
quantity index of year 2 output is P2 = $66,000. (These amounts are all calculated in Table 2.4,
they just are not labeled this way.) The chain-weighted index is just the geometric mean of the
Laspeyres and Paasche indexes: C1 = (L1 ยด P1)1/2 = (46,000 ยด 51,000)1/2 = $48,400; C2 = (L2 ยด P2)1/2
= (62,000 ยด 66,000)1/2 = $63,970.
Note that the growth rate of real GDP in this case is ($63,970 – $48,400)/$48,400 = 32.06%,
which is close to the average growth rate calculated by the Laspeyres (34.8%) and Paasche
(29.4%) indexes, which is 32.095%.
6. Inflation
a. Calculate inflation rate: p t+1 = (Pt+1 – Pt)/Pt = DPt+1/Pt
b. Text Fig. 2.4 shows the U.S. inflation rate since 1960 for the GDP deflator
7. Does CPI inflation overstate increases in the cost of living?
a. The Boskin Commission reported that the CPI was biased upward by as much as one to
two percentage points per year
b. One problem is that adjusting the price measures for changes in the quality of goods is
very difficult
c. Another problem is that price indexes with fixed sets of goods donโt reflect the substitution
by consumers that goes on when one good becomes relatively cheaper than another; this
problem is known as substitution bias
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
Chapter 2 The Measurement and Structure of the National Economy
25
Data Application
A symposium on the CPI appeared in the Journal of Economic Perspectives 12 (Winter 1998).
Many different aspects of measurement problems were explored. Although the BLS claims that
quality adjustments are made, William Nordhaus points out that other than in the categories of
new cars and trucks and womenโs apparel, only 0.1% of all priced commodities were deemed to
have quality changes in a recent year.
d. If inflation is overstated, then real incomes are higher than we thought and we have
overindexed payments like Social Security
e. Latest research (July 2006) suggests bias is still 1% per year or higher
C. Application: The Fedโs preferred inflation measures
1. The Federal Reserve focuses its attention on the personal consumption expenditures (PCE)
price index
a. The Fed forecasts both the overall PCE price index and the core PCE price index
2. The PCE price index is superior to the CPI because it avoids substitution bias and is revised
when better data are available
3. Differences between the PCE price index and the CPI include formulas used in their
calculation, coverage of different items, and weights given to different items
4. The Fed uses the core PCE price index to measure the underlying trend in inflation
5. But the Fed forecasts both the core and overall PCE price index because the Fed needs to
keep its eye on both underlying trends but also the actual inflation rate faced by households
6.
The inflation rate in the overall PCE price index tends to revert to the core measure after a
period when the two measures deviate (text Fig. 2.5)
Data Application
There are many problems with price indexes; they are imperfect measures of price changes.
What do the indexes do when new goods are introduced? What happens as more efficient stores
replace stores that had higher intermediate costs? How do we account for the fact that people
substitute cheaper goods for higher-priced goods? Inadequate treatment of these questions means
the measures of prices give an overestimate of the inflation rate. The BLS has fixed a number of
these problems in recent years, but some overestimate remains. In a comprehensive review of
these measurement issues, David E. Lebow and Jeremy B. Rudd (โMeasurement Error in the
Consumer Price Index: Where Do We Stand?โ Journal of Economic Literature (March 2003),
pp. 159โ201) conclude that the overestimate of inflation in the CPI became about 0.9% per year.
Robert Gordon suggests that the overstatement may still exceed 1.0 % per year (โThe Boskin
Commission Report: A Retrospective One Decade Later,โ NBER Working Paper No. 12311,
June 2006). More recently, Brent Moulton finds that the bias in CPI in 2018 is about 0.85% as
the Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of Labor Statistics have worked to reduce the bias
(โThe Measurement of Output, Prices, and Productivity: Whatโs Changed Since the Boskin
Commission?โ Brookings Institution, July 2018, www.brookings.edu/research/the-measurementof-output-prices-and-productivity).
Numerical Problems 7 and 9 give practice in calculating inflation rates.
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
26
V.
Abel/Bernanke/Croushore โข Macroeconomics, Tenth Edition
Interest Rates (Sec. 2.5)
A. Real vs. nominal interest rates
1. Interest rate: a rate of return promised by a borrower to a lender
2. Real interest rate: rate at which the real value of an asset increases over time
3. Nominal interest rate: rate at which the nominal value of an asset increases over time
4. Real interest rate = i – p
Text Fig. 2.6 plots nominal and real interest rates for the United States since 1960
(2.13)
B. The expected real interest rate
1. r = i – p e
2. If p = p e, real interest rate = expected real interest rate
Numerical Problem 8 provides practice in calculating real interest rates.
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
(2.14)
Chapter 2 The Measurement and Structure of the National Economy
n
Additional Issues for Classroom Discussion
1.
Welfare Does Not Equal GDP
27
You can get students involved in a useful discussion of how our national-income accounts fail to measure
our well-being. GDP covers only market activity. Ask your students to come up with some nonmarket
activities that are valuable to society, but which arenโt covered as part of GDP. Then you might discuss
some activities that increase GDP but reduce welfare in some way, such as activities that cause pollution.
The San Francisco think tank called โRedefining Progressโ collects data on what it labels โgenuine
progressโ and compares it to GDP. The genuine progress indicator (GPI) has been declining since the
mid-1960s, even though real GDP has been rising. Unlike GDP, which measures only market activity, the
GPI accounts for resource depletion, income distribution, housework and nonmarket transactions, changes
in leisure time, unemployment and underemployment, pollution, long-term environmental damage, the life
span of consumer durables and infrastructure, defensive expenditures, and sustainable investments.
2.
More Implications of Price Mismeasurement
Ask your students to explore the ramifications of the bias in the CPI and other price measures. If the CPI
has been overstated by one percentage point per year over the past decade, how much lower should Social
Security payments be? If you see data that say the real wage has barely grown over the past decade, where
real wage growth is measured by taking nominal wage growth and subtracting off the rate of inflation, what
does that imply about how fast real wages have truly grown? Some of the same biases to the price index
that apply to the CPI also apply to the GDP price index (though not the substitution bias). Using the GDP
price index, official government data show that multifactor productivity (a measure of average output that
accounts for growth in both capital and labor) has changed little over the past 20 years. But if the price
index is biased upward, what does that imply about both real GDP growth over the past 20 years and about
multifactor productivity over that time period? What other macroeconomic variables might be affected by
price mismeasurement?
3.
Should the CPI Measure Changes in Prices or Changes in the Cost of Living?
The Boskin Commission on the bias in the CPI raised a point that economists have known about for some
time. The economic concept that weโd like our price measures to capture is changes in the cost of living,
but our price indexes are set up to measure the change in average prices. The difference is subtle, yet
important. A great medical breakthrough, like the discovery of the polio vaccine, greatly improves the
quality of life, reducing the cost of living. Inventions like the vacuum cleaner or the transistor also changed
the things we do in daily life, vastly improving the quality of our lives. More recently, advances in computer
technology have changed the way we get information and the way businesses operate. But these great
inventions seldom have much of an impact on price indexes like the CPI or output measures like GDP.
The quality-of-life improvements engendered by new products are very difficult to measure. So the
government record-keepers let the income and price accounts reflect such quality changes in only a limited
way. But should they? The Boskin Commission recommended that the government statistical agencies try
to measure changes in the quality of life, rather than just measuring the prices of existing goods. Yet there
can never be solid knowledge of exactly how much better new inventions make our lives. So should the
government agencies simply continue to do what theyโve been doing, and just measure prices? Or should
they take their โbest guessโ as to the improvement in our lives that new inventions and discoveries cause?
Would the fact that such a โguessโ influences things like the monthly payments to Social Security
recipients affect your decision?
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
28
n
Abel/Bernanke/Croushore โข Macroeconomics, Tenth Edition
Answers to Textbook Problems
Review Questions
1. The three approaches to national income accounting are the product approach, the income approach,
and the expenditure approach. They all give the same answer because they are designed that way; any
entry based on one approach has an entry in the other approaches with the same value. Whenever
output is produced and sold, its production is counted in the product approach, its sale is counted in
the expenditure approach, and the funds received by the seller are counted in the income approach.
2. Goods are measured at market value in GDP accounting so that different types of goods and services
can be added together. Using market prices allows us to count up the total dollar value of all the
economyโs output. The problem with this approach is that not all goods and services are sold in
markets, so we may not be able to count everything. Important examples are homemaking and
environmental quality.
3. Intermediate goods and services are used up in producing other goods in the same period (year) in
which they were produced, while final goods and services are those that are purchased by consumers
or are capital goods that are used to produce future output. The distinction is important, because we
want to count only the value of final goods produced in the economy, not the value of goods
produced each step along the way.
4. GNP is the market value of final goods and services newly produced by domestic factors of production
during the current period, whereas GDP is production taking place within a country. Thus, GNP
differs from GDP when foreign factors are used to produce output in a country, or when domestic
factors are used to produce output in another country. GDP = GNP – NFP, where NFP = net factor
payments from abroad, which equals income paid to domestic factors of production by the rest of the
world minus income paid to foreign factors of production by the domestic economy. A country that
employs many foreign workers will likely have negative NFP, so GDP will be higher than GNP.
5.
The four components of spending are consumption, investment, government purchases, and net exports.
Imports must be subtracted, because they are produced abroad and we want GDP to count only those
goods and services that are produced within the country. For example, suppose a car built in Japan is
imported into the United States. The car counts as consumption spending in U.S. GDP, but is
subtracted as an import as well, so on net it does not affect U.S. GDP. However, it is counted in
Japanโs GDP as an export.
6. Private saving is private disposable income minus consumption. Private disposable income is total
output minus taxes paid plus transfers and interest received from the government. Private saving is
used to finance investment spending, the government budget deficit, and the current account.
National saving is private saving plus government saving.
7. National wealth is the total wealth of the residents of a country, and consists of its domestic physical
assets and net foreign assets. Wealth is important because the long-run economic well-being of a
country depends on it. National wealth is related to national saving because national saving is the
flow of additions to the stock of national wealth.
8. Real GDP is the useful concept for figuring out a countryโs growth performance. Nominal GDP may
rise because of increases in prices rather than growth in real output.
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
Chapter 2 The Measurement and Structure of the National Economy
29
9. The CPI is a price index that is calculated as the value of a fixed set of consumer goods and services
at current prices divided by the value of the fixed set at base-year prices. CPI inflation is the growth
rate of the CPI. CPI inflation overstates true inflation because it is hard to measure changes in quality,
and because the price index doesnโt account for substitution away from goods that become relatively
more expensive toward goods that become relatively cheaper.
10. The nominal interest rate is the rate at which the nominal (or dollar) value of an asset increases over
time. The real interest rate is the rate at which the real value or purchasing power of an asset increases
over time, and is equal to the nominal interest rate minus the inflation rate. The expected real interest
rate is the rate at which the real value of an asset is expected to increase over time. It is equal to the
nominal interest rate minus the expected inflation rate. The concept that is most important to borrowers
and lenders is the expected real interest rate, because it affects their decisions to borrow or lend.
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
30
Abel/Bernanke/Croushore โข Macroeconomics, Tenth Edition
Numerical Problems
1.
GDP is the value of all final goods and services produced during the year. The final output of coconuts
is 1000, which is worth 500 fish, because two coconuts are worth one fish. The final output of fish is
500 fish. So in terms of fish, GDP consists of 500 fish worth of coconuts plus 500 fish, with a total
value of 1000 fish.
To find consumption and investment, we must find out what happens to all the coconuts and fish.
Gilligan consumes all his 200 coconuts (worth 100 fish) and 100 fish, so his consumption is worth
200 fish. The Professor stores 100 coconuts with a value of 50 fish. In an ideal accounting system,
these stored coconuts would be treated as investment. However, in the national income accounts,
because it is so difficult to tell when durable goods are consumed and when they are saved, they are
counted as consumption. So the Professorโs consumption consists of 800 coconuts (value 400 fish)
and 400 fish, for a total value of 800 fish. Thus, the economyโs total consumption is valued at 1000
fish and investment is zero.
In terms of income, Gilliganโs income is clearly worth 200 fish (100 fish plus 200 coconuts worth
100 fish). The Professorโs income is 800 coconuts (1000 coconuts minus the 200 coconuts paid to
Gilligan) plus 400 fish (500 fish minus 100 fish paid to Gilligan). In terms of fish, the Professorโs
income has a value of 800 fish.
This question illustrates some of the nuances of national income accounting. Many difficult choices
and measurement issues are involved in constructing the accounts. Here, for example, it is clear that
what we call consumption really isnโt just the amount of goods consumers use up during the year, but
also includes consumption goods that are purchased but saved for the future. Since there is no way to
measure when goods are used after they are purchased, the accounts are unable to distinguish
consumption from storage of goods.
2.
(a) Furniture made in North Carolina that is bought by consumers counts as consumption,
so consumption increases by $6 billion, investment is unchanged, government purchases are
unchanged, net exports are unchanged, and GDP increases by $6 billion.
(b) Furniture made in Sweden that is bought by consumers counts as consumption and imports,
so consumption increases by $6 billion, investment is unchanged, government purchases are
unchanged, net exports fall by $6 billion, and GDP is unchanged.
(c) Furniture made in North Carolina that is bought by businesses counts as investment,
so consumption is unchanged, investment increases by $6 billion, government purchases
are unchanged, net exports are unchanged, and GDP increases by $6 billion.
(d) Furniture made in Sweden that is bought by businesses counts as investment and imports,
so consumption is unchanged, investment increases by $6 billion, government purchases are
unchanged, net exports decline by $6 billion, and GDP is unchanged.
3.
(a) ABC produces output valued at $2 million and has total expenses of $1.3 million ($1 million for
labor, $0.1 million interest, $0.2 million taxes). So its profits are $0.7 million. XYZ produces
output valued at $3.8 million ($3 million for the three computers that were sold, plus $0.8 million
for the unsold computer in inventory) and has expenses of $3.2 million ($2 million for components,
$0.8 million for labor, and $0.4 million for taxes). So its profits are $0.6 million.
According to the product approach, the GDP contributions of these companies are $3.8 million,
the value of the final product of XYZ. ABCโs production is of an intermediate good, used
completely by XYZ, and so is not counted in GDP.
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
Chapter 2 The Measurement and Structure of the National Economy
31
According to the expenditure approach, the GDP contribution is also $3.8 million, with
$3 million (of sold computers) adding to the capital stock (as investment spending), and $0.8
million (the unsold computer) as inventory investment.
The income approach yields the same GDP total contribution. The amounts are:
ABC
XYZ
TOTAL
Labor
Profit
Taxes
$1.0 million
$0.7 million
$0.2 million
$0.8 million
$0.6 million
$0.4 million
$1.8 million
$1.3 million
$0.6 million
Interest
$0.1 million
$0.0 million
$0.1 million
Total of all incomes = $3.8 million
(b) If ABC pays an additional $.5 million for computer chips from abroad, the results change
slightly. The correct answer is easiest to see using the expenditure approach. As in part a, there is
$3.8 million spent on final goods, but now there are also net exports of -$0.5 million. So the total
expenditure on domestically produced goods is only $3.3 million. The product approach gets the
same answer because the $0.5 million is a contribution to GDP of the country in which the chips
were made, and so must be deducted from the GDP of the United States. The value added in the
United States is only $3.3 million. Finally, the income approach gives the same answer as in
part a, except that the cost of importing the chips reduces ABCโs profits by $0.5 million, so the
sum of the incomes is only $3.3 million.
4.
(a) Product approach: $2 = gas stationโs value added = $28 product minus $26 value of product
produced in the previous year. Expenditure approach: $2 = $28 consumption spending plus
inventory investment of -$26. Income approach: $2 paid to the factors of production at the gas
station (wages of employees, interest, taxes, profits).
(b) Product approach: $60,000 brokerโs fee for providing brokerage services. Expenditure approach:
$60,000 counts as residential investment made by the homebuyer. The important point here is
that the transfer of an existing good, even at a higher value than that at which it was originally
sold, does not add to GDP. Income approach: $60,000 income to the broker for wages,
profits, and so on.
(c) Product approach: $40,000 salary plus $16,000 childcare equals $56,000. Note that there is a
sense in which the childcare is an intermediate service and should not be counted, because
without it the homemaker would not be able to work. But in practice there is no way to separate
such intermediate services from final services, so they are all added to GDP. Expenditure
approach: $56,000 ($16,000 consumption spending on child care services plus $40,000 in
categories that depend on what the homemaker spends his or her income). Income approach:
$56,000 ($40,000 compensation of homemaker plus $16,000 income to the factors producing
the child care: employeesโ wages, interest, taxes, profits).
(d) Product approach: $100 million of a capital good. Since it is produced with local labor and
materials, and assuming no payments go to Japanese factors of production, this is all added
to U.S. GDP. Expenditure approach: $100 million net exports, since the plant is owned by the
Japanese. (It is not part of gross domestic investment because the plant is not a capital good
owned by U.S. residents.) Income approach: $100 million paid to U.S. factors of production.
(e) Product approach: $0 because nothing is produced. Expenditure approach: $0 because this is a
transfer, not a government purchase of goods or services. Income approach: $0, because this is
not a payment to a factor of production, just a transfer.
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
32
Abel/Bernanke/Croushore โข Macroeconomics, Tenth Edition
(f ) Product approach: $5,000 worth of advertising services. Expenditure approach: $5,000 of
government purchases. Income approach: $5,000 compensation of employees.
(g) Product approach: $120 million composed of $100 million of new cars produced plus $20 million
of sales services provided by the consortium ($60 million sales price minus $40 million cost).
Expenditure approach: $100 million by Hertz as investment plus $60 million by the public for
consumption of the used cars minus $40 million of investment goods sold by Hertz, for a total of
$120 million. Income approach: $100 million to the factors of production of GM plus $20 million
in payments to the factors of production and profits for the consortium.
5.
Given data: I = 40, G = 30, GNP = 200, CA = -20 = NX + NFP, T = 60, TR = 25, INT = 15, NFP =
7 – 9 = -2. Since GDP = GNP – NFP, GDP = 200 – (-2) = 202 = Y. Since NX + NFP = CA, NX =
CA – NFP = -20 – (-2) = -18. Since Y = C + I + G + NX, C = Y – (I + G + NX) = 202 – (40 + 30 +
(-18)) = 150.
Spvt = (Y + NFP – T + TR + INT) – C = (202 + (-2) – 60 + 25 + 15) -150 = 30. Sgovt = (T – TR – INT)
– G = (60 – 25 – 15) – 30 = -10. S = Spvt + Sgovt = 30 + (-10) = 20.
(a) Consumption = 150
(b) Net exports = -18
(c) GDP = 202
(d) Net factor payments from abroad = -2
(e) Private saving = 30
(f ) Government saving = -10
(g) National saving = 20
6.
Base-Year Quantities at Current-Year Prices
At Base-Year Prices
Apples
3000 ยด $3 = $ 9,000
3000 ยด $2 = $ 6,000
Bananas
6000 ยด $2 = $12,000
6000 ยด $3 = $18,000
Oranges
8000 ยด $5 = $40,000
$61,000
8000 ยด $4 = $32,000
$56,000
Total
Current-Year Quantities at Current-Year Prices
At Base-Year Prices
Apples
4,000 ยด $3 = $ 12,000
4,000 ยด $2 = $
Bananas
14,000 ยด $2 = $ 28,000
14,000 ยด $3 = $ 42,000
Oranges
32,000 ยด $5 = $160,000
32,000 ยด $4 = $128,000
$200,000
$178,000
Total
8,000
(a) Nominal GDP is just the dollar value of production in a year at prices in that year. Nominal GDP
is $56 thousand in the base year and $200 thousand in the current year. Nominal GDP grew
257% between the base year and the current year: [($200,000/$56,000) – 1] ยด 100% = 257%.
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
Chapter 2 The Measurement and Structure of the National Economy
33
(b) Real GDP is calculated by finding the value of production in each year at base-year prices.
Thus, from the table above, real GDP is $56,000 in the base year and $178,000 in the current year.
In percentage terms, real GDP increases from the base year to the current year by
[($178,000/$56,000) – 1] ยด 100% = 218%.
(c) The GDP deflator is the ratio of nominal GDP to real GDP. In the base year, nominal GDP
equals real GDP, so the GDP deflator is 1. In the current year, the GDP deflator is
$200,000/$178,000 = 1.124. Thus, the GDP deflator changes by [(1.124/1) – 1] ยด 100% = 12.4%
from the base year to the current year.
(d) Nominal GDP rose 257%, prices rose 12.4%, and real GDP rose 218%, so most of the increase
in nominal GDP is because of the increase in real output, not prices. Notice that the quantity of
oranges quadrupled and the quantity of bananas more than doubled.
7.
Calculating inflation rates:
1929โ30: [(50.0/51.3) – 1] ยด 100% = -2.5%
1930โ31: [(45.6/50.0) – 1] ยด 100% = -8.8%
1931โ32: [(40.9/45.6) – 1] ยด 100% = -10.3%
1932โ33: [(38.8/40.9) – 1] ยด 100% = -5.1%
These all show deflation (prices are declining over time), whereas recently we have had nothing but
inflation (prices rising over time).
8.
The nominal interest rate is [(545/500) – 1] ยด 100% = 9%. The inflation rate is [(214/200) – 1] ยด
100% = 7%. So the real interest rate is 2% (9% nominal rate – 7% inflation rate). Expected inflation
was only [(210/200) – 1] ยด 100% = 5%, so the expected real interest rate was 4% (9% nominal rate 5% expected inflation rate).
9.
(a) The annual rate of inflation from January 1, 2014 to January 1, 2016, is 10%. This can be found
by calculating the constant rate of inflation that would raise the deflator from 200 to 242 in two
years. This gives the equation (1 + p)(1 + p) = (242/200), which has the solution p = 10%.
An easy way to think about this question is this. A constant inflation rate of p raises the deflator
from 200 on January 1, 2014 to 200 ยด (1 + p) on January 1, 2015, and to 200 ยด (1 + p) ยด (1 + p) =
242 on January 1, 2016. So we need to solve the expression (1 + p)2 = 242/200.
(b) By similar reasoning, the inflation rate over the three-year period is (1 + p)3 = 266.2/200,
or p = 10%.
(c) We can derive a general expression in the same way:
1 + p = P1/P0
1 + p = P2/P1
รรร
รรร
รรร
1 + p = Pn/Pnโ1
Multiplying all these lines together, we get:
(1 + p)n = (P1/P0) ยด (P2/P1) ยด รรร ยด (Pn/Pn โ 1) = Pn/P0
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
34
Abel/Bernanke/Croushore โข Macroeconomics, Tenth Edition
Analytical Problems
1.
The key to this question is that real GDP is not the same thing as well-being. People may be better off
even if real GDP is lower; for example, this may occur because the improvement in the health of
workers is more valuable to society than the loss of GDP due to the regulation. Ideally, we would like
to be able to compare the costs and benefits of such regulations; they should be put in place if the
overall costs (the reduced GDP in this case) are valued less than the overall benefits (the workersโ
health).
2.
National saving does not rise because of the switch to CheapCall because although consumption
spending declines by $2 million, total expenditures (GDP) decline by the same amount, and
expenditures equal income. Because income and spending both decline by the same amount, national
saving is unchanged.
3.
(a) The problem in a planned economy is that prices do not measure market value. When the price
of an item is too low, then goods are really more expensive than their listed price suggestsโwe
should include in their market value the value of time spent by consumers waiting to make
purchases. Because the itemโs value exceeds its cost, measured GDP is too low.
When the price of an item is too high, goods stocked on the shelves may be valued too highly.
This results in an overvaluation of firmsโ inventories, and as a result the measured GDP is too
high.
A possible strategy for dealing with this problem is to have GDP analysts estimate what the market
price should be (perhaps by looking at prices of the same goods in market economies) and use
this โshadowโ price in the GDP calculations.
(b) The goods and services that people produce at home are not counted in the GDP figures because
they are not sold on the market, making their value difficult to measure. One way to do it might
be to look at the standard of living relative to a market economy, and estimate what income it
would take in a market economy to support that standard of living.
4.
From Eq. (2.3), and using GPDI for gross private domestic investment,
Y = C + GPDI + (GCE + GI) + NX.
From Eq. (2.6), Spvt = Y + NFP โ T + TR + INT โ C.
Substituting Eq. (2.3) into (2.6) to eliminate Y, we get
Spvt = C + GPDI + (GCE + GI) + NX + NFP โ T + TR + INT โ C
= GPDI + (GCE + GI) + NX + NFP โ T + TR + INT.
Under the new definition, Sg = T โ TR โ INT โ GCE.
Then, because S = Spvt + Sg,
S = GPDI + (GCE + GI) + NX + NFP โ T + TR + INT + T โ TR โ INT โ GCE
= GPDI + GI + NX + NFP.
We define I = GPDI + GI, and since CA = NX + NFP, we have
S = I + CA.
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
Chapter 2 The Measurement and Structure of the National Economy
35
Example from 2015:Q1 (amounts in billions of dollars): Gross saving = 3366.8, gross domestic
investment = 3589.2, and current account balance = โ475.1. So gross domestic investment +
current account balance = 3114.1, which is 252.7 smaller than gross saving. Capital account
transactions = 0.4 and the statistical discrepancy is โ252.3, so if we add the statistical
discrepancy to gross saving, we get 3114.5. If we add capital account transactions to the sum of
investment and current account balance, we also get 3114.5.
Working with Macroeconomic Data
1.
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
36
Abel/Bernanke/Croushore โข Macroeconomics, Tenth Edition
Consumption generally increased as a percentage of GDP from 1965 to 2018. I/GDP generally
increased from 1960 to 2018 but is more volatile than C/GDP. G/GDP generally decreased from
1960 to 2018. X/GDP and M/GDP generally increased from 1960 to 2018.
2.
S/GDP rose sharply in the recession in 2008-2009, peaked at 24% in 2012, and fell a bit after that
before rising in 2018. I/GDP fell significantly from 2008 to 2010 and rose steadily from 2010 to
2014. National investment can exceed national saving if we borrow from foreign countries.
3.
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
Chapter 2 The Measurement and Structure of the National Economy
37
The CPI measure is based only on consumer prices, while the GDP deflator measures the prices of all
goods included in GDP. The inflation measures are roughly similar most of the time.
4.
The nominal interest rate sometimes rises with inflation, but other times it moves in the opposite
direction. The real interest rate is not constant; it is sometimes positive and sometimes negative.
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
38
Abel/Bernanke/Croushore โข Macroeconomics, Tenth Edition
5.
As of July 2018, the average difference in the growth rates of GDP and GDI in the past five years
was 0.2%.
6.
The quarterly data using the percent change from the previous quarter is similar but a muted version
of the annualized quarterly growth rate, while the percent change from a year ago is much smoother.
Annualized quarterly growth rates are the most volatile, while quarterly data using the percent change
from a year ago are the least volatile.
ยฉ2020 Pearson Education, Inc.
Document Preview (23 of 423 Pages)
User generated content is uploaded by users for the purposes of learning and should be used following SchloarOn's honor code & terms of service.
You are viewing preview pages of the document. Purchase to get full access instantly.
-37%
Solution Manual For Macroeconomics, 10th Edition
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
24/7 Live Chat
Instant Download
100% Confidential
Store
Amelia Rodriguez
0 (0 Reviews)
Best Selling
2023-2024 ATI Pediatrics Proctored Exam with Answers (139 Solved Questions)
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
Chemistry: Principles And Reactions, 7th Edition Test Bank
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
Test Bank for Hospitality Facilities Management and Design, 4th Edition
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
The World Of Customer Service, 3rd Edition Test Bank
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
Data Structures and Other Objects Using C++ 4th Edition Solution Manual
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
Solution Manual for Designing the User Interface: Strategies for Effective Human-Computer Interaction, 6th Edition
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)