Preview Extract
International Macroeconomics 4th Edition Feenstra Solutions Manual
Full Download: https://testbanklive.com/download/international-macroeconomics-4th-edition-feenstra-solutions-manual/
2 (13) Introduction to Exchange Rates and the Foreign Exchange Market
1. Discovering Data Not all pegs are created equal! In this question you will explore
trends in exchange rates. Go to the St. Louis Federal Reserveโs Economic Data (FRED)
website at https://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/ and download the daily United States
exchange rates with Venezuela, India, and Hong Kong from 1990 to present. These can
be found most easily by searching for the country names and โdaily exchange rate.โ
a. Plot the Indian rupee to U.S. dollar exchange rate over this period. For what years
does the rupee appear to be pegged to the dollar? Does this peg break? If so, how
many times?
Answer: The rupee appears to be pegged to the U.S. dollar at various rates from 1991
until about 1998 with intermittent volatility at places the peg appears to break. There
are four distinct rates at which this peg remains, the longest of which lasting over two
years from 1993 until mid 1995.
80.0000
70.0000
Rupee/Dollar Exchange Rate
60.0000
50.0000
40.0000
30.0000
10.0000
0.0000
1990-01-02
1991-01-02
1992-01-02
1993-01-02
1994-01-02
1995-01-02
1996-01-02
1997-01-02
1998-01-02
1999-01-02
2000-01-02
2001-01-02
2002-01-02
2003-01-02
2004-01-02
2005-01-02
2006-01-02
2007-01-02
2008-01-02
2009-01-02
2010-01-02
2011-01-02
2012-01-02
2013-01-02
2014-01-02
2015-01-02
2016-01-02
20.0000
b. How would you characterize the relationship between the rupee and the dollar from
1998โ2008? Does it appear to be fixed, crawling, or floating during this period? How
would you characterize it from 2008 onward?
Answer: Over this period the exchange rate appears to be a crawling peg. Although
this crawl is relatively flat for a few years at the beginning of this period, it appears
free to move. However, the lack of short-term volatility suggests that the exchange
rate is still being controlled and is hence crawling. From 2008 onward this appears to
be a freely floating currency. The line becomes more erratic with a greater deal of
short-term volatility.
c. The Hong Kong dollar has maintained its peg with the United States dollar since
1983. Over the course of the period that you have downloaded what are the highest
and lowest values for this exchange rate?
Full download all chapters instantly please go to Solutions Manual, Test Bank site: testbanklive.com
Answer: This peg has never broken over this period (although there is some
movement if you allow the axis to be small enough). The highest rate that it has
attained is 7.8289 Hong Kong dollars per US dollar on August 6, 2007, at the height
of the financial crisis. The lowest it has gone is 7.7085 on October 6, 2003.
Hong Kong/US Exchange Rate
9.0000
8.8000
8.6000
8.4000
8.2000
8.0000
7.8000
7.6000
2016-01-02
2015-01-02
2014-01-02
2013-01-02
2012-01-02
2011-01-02
2010-01-02
2009-01-02
2008-01-02
2007-01-02
2006-01-02
2005-01-02
2004-01-02
2003-01-02
2002-01-02
2001-01-02
2000-01-02
1999-01-02
1998-01-02
1997-01-02
1996-01-02
1995-01-02
1994-01-02
1993-01-02
1992-01-02
7.0000
1991-01-02
7.2000
1990-01-02
7.4000
d. Venezuela has been less successful in its attempts to fix against the dollar. Since
1995 how many times has the Venezuelan bolรญvar peg to the dollar broken? What is
the average length of a peg? What is the average size of a devaluation?
Answer: I count seven breaks in this peg over this period. In 1998 they appear to
move to a slow and managed crawl before floating for a short time and returning to a
fixed rate. The longest period of any one peg appears to be when the exchange rate
was set at 2.14 bolรญvar/dollar for about five years between 2005 and 2010.
12
10
Venezuela/US Exchange Rate
8
6
4
2
0
2. Refer to the exchange rates given in the following table:
Country (currency)
Australia (dollar)
Canada (dollar)
Denmark (krone)
Eurozone (euro)
Hong Kong (dollar)
India (rupee)
Japan (yen)
Mexico (peso)
Sweden (krona)
United Kingdom (pound)
United States (dollar)
January 20, 2016
FX per $ FX per ยฃ
1.459
2.067
1.451
2.056
6.844
9.694
0.917
1.299
7.827
11.086
68.05
96.39
116.38
164.84
18.60
26.346
8.583
12.157
0.706
1.000
1.000
1.416
January 20, 2015
FX per โฌ FX per $
1.414
1.223
1.398
1.209
7.434
6.430
1.000
0.865
8.962
7.752
71.60
61.64
136.97
118.48
16.933
14.647
9.458
8.181
0.763
0.600
1.156
1.000
Data from: U.S. Federal Reserve Board of Governors, H.10 release: Foreign Exchange
Rates.
Based on the table provided, answer the following questions:
a. Compute the U.S. dollarโyen exchange rate E$/ยฅ and the U.S. dollarโCanadian
dollar exchange rate E$/C$ on January 20, 2016, and January 20, 2015.
Answer:
U.S. dollarโyen rates:
January 20, 2015: E$/ยฅ = 1/(118.48) = $0.0084/ยฅ
January 20, 2016: E$/ยฅ = 1/(116.38) = $0.0086/ยฅ
January 20, 2015: E$/C$ = 1/(1.209) = $0.8271/C$
January 20, 2016: E$/C$ = 1/(1.451) = $0.6892/C$
b. What happened to the value of the U.S. dollar relative to the Japanese yen and
Canadian dollar between January 20, 2015, and January 20, 2016? Compute the
percentage change in the value of the U.S. dollar relative to each currency using
the U.S. dollarโforeign currency exchange rates you computed in (a).
Answer: Between January 20, 2015, and January 20, 2016, the Japanese yen
appreciated, and the Canadian dollar depreciated relative to the U.S. dollar.
The percentage appreciation of the yen relative to the U.S. dollar is:
%โE$/ยฅ = ($0.0086 โ $0.0084)/$0.0084 = 2.38%
The percentage depreciation of the Canadian dollar relative to the U.S. dollar is:
%โE$/C$ = ($0.6892 โ $0.8271)/$0.8271 = -16.67%
c. Using the information in the table for January 20, 2016, compute the Danish
kroneโCanadian dollar exchange rate Ekrone/C$.
Answer: Ekrone/C$ = (6.844 kr/$)/(1.451 C$/$) = 4.7167 kr/C$.
d. Visit the website of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System at
http://www.federalreserve.gov/. Click on โEconomic Research and Dataโ and
then โData Download Program (DDP)โ Download the H.10 release Foreign
Exchange Rates (weekly data available). What has happened to the value of the
U.S. dollar relative to the Canadian dollar, Japanese yen, and Danish krone since
January 20, 2016?
Answer: Answers will depend on the latest data update.
Based on the foreign exchange rates (H.10) released on March 20, 2017, the
exchange rate for the Canadian dollar, yen, and krone was 1.3366, 112.67, and
6.9207, respectively. Thus, while the Canadian dollarโU.S. dollar and the yenโ
dollar exchange rates have depreciated by about 7.88% and 3.19%, respectively.
The krone has appreciated by about 1.12%.
e. Using the information from (d), what has happened to the value of the U.S. dollar
relative to the British pound and the euro? Note: The H.10 release quotes these
exchange rates as U.S. dollars per unit of foreign currency in line with longstanding market conventions.
Answer: Answers will depend on the latest data update.
Based on the foreign exchange rates (H.10) released on March 20, 2017, the U.K.
poundโU.S. dollar and euroโU.S. dollar rates were 0.808 and 0.931, respectively.
Thus, relative to the U.S. dollar, the pound appreciated by 14.45% and the euro
appreciated by 1.53%.
3. Consider the United States and the countries it trades with the most (measured in
trade volume): Canada, Mexico, China, and Japan. For simplicity, assume these are
the only four countries with which the United States trades. Trade shares (trade
weights) and U.S. nominal exchange rates for these four countries are as follows:
Country (currency)
Canada (dollar)
Mexico (peso)
China (yuan)
Japan (yen)
Share of Trade
36%
28%
20%
16%
$ per FX in 2015
0.8271
0.0683
0.1608
0.0080
$ per FX in 2016
0.6892
0.0538
0.1522
0.0086
a. Compute the percentage change from 2015 to 2016 in the four U.S. bilateral
exchange rates (defined as U.S. dollars per unit of foreign exchange, or FX) in the
table provided.
Answer:
%โE$/C$ = (0.6892 โ 0.8271)/0.8271 = โ16.67%
%โE$/pesos = (0.0538 โ 0.0683)/0.0683 = โ21.23%
%โE$/yuan = (0.1522 โ 0.1608)/0.1608 = โ5.35%
%โE$/ยฅ = (0.0086 โ 0.008/0.008 = 7.50%
b. Use the trade shares as weights to compute the percentage change in the nominal
effective exchange rate for the United States between 2015 and 2016 (in U.S.
dollars per foreign currency basket).
Answer: The trade-weighted percentage change in the exchange rate is:
%โE = 0.36(%โE$/C$) + 0.28(%โE$/pesos) + 0.20(%โE$/yuan) + 0.16(%โE$/ยฅ)
%โE = 0.36(โ16.67 %) + 0.28(โ21.23%) + 0.20(โ5.35%) + 0.16(7.50%) = โ11.82%
c. Based on your answer to (b), what happened to the value of the U.S. dollar against
this basket between 2015 and 2016? How does this compare with the change in
the value of the U.S. dollar relative to the Mexican peso? Explain your answer.
Answer: The dollar appreciated by 11.82% against the basket of currencies. Visร -vis the peso, the dollar appreciated by 21.23%. The average depreciation is
smaller because the dollar depreciated by only 5.35% against China with a 20%
trade share and appreciated against the yen with a 16% trade share.
4. Go to the FRED website: http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/. Locate the monthly
exchange rate data for the following:
Look at the graphs and make your own judgment as to whether each currency was
fixed (peg or band), crawling (peg or band), or floating relative to the U.S. dollar
during each time frame given.
a. Canada (dollar), 1980โ2012
Answer: Floating exchange rate
b. China (yuan), 1999โ2004, 2005โ09, and 2009โ10
Answer: 1999โ2004: fixed exchange rate; 2005โ09: gradual appreciation vis-ร vis the dollar; again fixed for 2009โ10
c. Mexico (peso), 1993โ95 and 1995โ2012
Answer: 1993โ95: crawl; 1995โ2012: floating (with some evidence of a managed
float)
d. Thailand (baht), 1986โ97 and 1997โ2012
Answer: 1986โ97: fixed exchange rate; 1997โ2012: floating
e. Venezuela (bolรญvar), 2003โ12
Answer: fixed exchange rate (with occasional adjustments)
5. Describe the different ways in which the government may intervene in the forex
market. Why does the government have the ability to intervene in this way, while
private actors do not?
Answer: The government may participate in the forex market in a number of ways:
capital controls, establishing an official market (with fixed rates) for forex
transactions, and forex intervention by buying and selling currencies in the forex
markets. The government has the ability to intervene in a way that private actors do
not because through its central bank it has unlimited stock of its own currency and
usually a large stock of foreign reserves. Its intervention is guided by policy rather
than merely making profits on currency trade, which is the case with the private
sector.
Work it out. Consider a Dutch investor with 1,000 euros to place in a bank deposit in
either the Netherlands or Great Britain. The (one-year) interest rate on bank deposits
is 1% in Britain and 5% in the Netherlands. The (one-year) forward euroโpound
exchange rate is 1.65 euros per pound and the spot rate is 1.5 euros per pound.
Answer the following questions, using the exact equations for uncovered interest
parity (UIP) and covered interest parity (CIP) as necessary.
a. What is the euro-denominated return on Dutch deposits for this investor?
Answer: The investorโs return on euro-denominated Dutch deposits is equal to
โฌ1,050 = โฌ1,000 ร (1 + 0.05).
b. What is the (riskless) euro-denominated return on British deposits for this investor
using forward cover?
Answer: The euro-denominated return on British deposits using forward cover is
equal to โฌ1,111 (= โฌ1,000 ร (1.65/1.5) ร (1 + 0.01)).
c. Is there an arbitrage opportunity here? Explain why or why not. Is this an
equilibrium in the forward exchange rate market?
Answer: Yes, there is an arbitrage opportunity. The euro-denominated return on
British deposits is higher than that on Dutch deposits. The net return on each euro
deposit in a Dutch bank is equal to 5% versus 11.1% (= (1.65/1.5) ร (1 + 0.01))
on a British deposit (using forward cover). This is not an equilibrium in the
forward exchange market. The actions of traders seeking to exploit the arbitrage
opportunity will cause the spot and forward rates to change.
d. If the spot rate is 1.5 euros per pound, and interest rates are as stated previously,
what is the equilibrium forward rate, according to CIP?
Answer: CIP implies Fโฌ/ยฃ = Eโฌ/ยฃ (1 + iโฌ)/(1 + iยฃ) = 1.65 ร 1.05/1.01 = โฌ1.72 per ยฃ.
e. Suppose the forward rate takes the value given by your answer to (d). Compute
the forward premium on the British pound for the Dutch investor (where
exchange rates are in euros per pound). Is it positive or negative? Why do
investors require this premium/discount in equilibrium?
Answer: Forward premium = (Fโฌ/ยฃ/Eโฌ/ยฃ โ 1) = (1.72/1.50) โ 1 = 0.1467 or
14.67%. The existence of a positive forward premium would imply that investors
expect the euro to depreciate relative to the British pound. Therefore, when
establishing forward contracts, the forward rate is higher than the current spot
rate.
f. If UIP holds, what is the expected depreciation of the euro (against the pound)
over one year?
Answer: If UIP holds, the expected euroโpound exchange rate is the same as the
forward rate, that is, โฌ 1.72 per ยฃ (see part (d) above). The expected depreciation
of Euro against pound is therefore 14.67%.
g. Based on your answer to (f), what is the expected euroโpound exchange rate one
year ahead?
Answer: Following the answer to parts (d) and (f), the expected euroโpound
exchange rate is โฌ1.72 per ยฃ or 1/1.72 = 0.5814 ยฃ/โฌ.
6. Suppose quotes for the dollarโeuro exchange rate E$/โฌ are as follows: in New York
$1.05 per euro, and in Tokyo $1.15 per euro. Describe how investors use arbitrage to
take advantage of the difference in exchange rates. Explain how this process will
affect the dollar price of the euro in New York and Tokyo.
Answer: Investors will buy euros in New York at a price of $1.05 each because this
is relatively cheaper than the price in Tokyo. They will then sell these euros in Tokyo
at a price of $1.15, earning a $0.10 profit on each euro. With the influx of buyers in
New York, the price of euros in New York will increase. With the influx of traders
selling euros in Tokyo, the price of euros in Tokyo will decrease. This price
adjustment continues until the exchange rates are equal in both markets.
7. You are a financial adviser to a U.S. corporation that expects to receive a payment of
60 million Japanese yen in 180 days for goods exported to Japan. The current spot
rate is 100 yen per U.S. dollar (E$/ยฅ = 0.01000). You are concerned that the U.S.
dollar is going to appreciate against the yen over the next six months.
a. Assuming the exchange rate remains unchanged, how much does your firm expect
to receive in U.S. dollars?
Answer: The firm expects to receive $600,000 (= ยฅ60,000,000/100).
b. How much would your firm receive (in U.S. dollars) if the dollar appreciated to
110 yen per U.S. dollar (E$/ยฅ = 0.00909)?
Answer: The firm would receive $545,454 (= ยฅ60,000,000/110).
c. Describe how you could use an options contract to hedge against the risk of losses
associated with the potential appreciation in the U.S. dollar.
Answer: The firm could buy ยฅ60 million in call options on dollars, say, for
example, at a rate of 105ยฅ per dollar. A call option gives the buyer a right to buy
dollars at the price agreed upon. If the dollar appreciates such that its price rises
above 105ยฅ, say to 110ยฅ, the firm will exercise the option. This ensures the firmโs
yen receipts will at least be worth $571,428 (= ยฅ60,000,000/105).
8. Consider how transactions costs affect foreign currency exchange. Rank each of the
following foreign exchanges according to their probable spread (between the โbuy atโ
and โsell forโ bilateral exchange rates) and justify your ranking.
a. An American returning from a trip to Turkey wants to exchange his Turkish lira
for U.S. dollars at the airport.
b. Citigroup and HSBC, both large commercial banks located in the United States
and United Kingdom, respectively, need to clear several large checks drawn on
accounts held by each bank.
c. Honda Motor Company needs to exchange yen for U.S. dollars to pay American
workers at its Ohio manufacturing plant.
d. A Canadian tourist in Germany pays for her hotel room using a credit card.
Answer: Ranking (highest spread first): (a), (d), (c), (b). Both (a) and (d) involve
small transactions that will involve a go-between who will charge a premium to
convert the currency. (d) involves a credit card company (a commercial bank or
nonbank financial institution) that likely is involved in large volumes of transactions
each day. (c) involves a corporation that can negotiate a better rate (versus an
individual) because it will likely engage in a large currency exchange, or Honda could
simply enter the market without going through a broker. Finally, (b) involves two
large commercial banks that regularly engage in large-volume foreign exchange
trading.
12 The Global Macroeconomy
Notes to the Instructor
Chapter Summary
This chapter provides students with a broad overview of international macroeconomics.
The chapter uses several key concepts to introduce the subject to students without formal
modeling. At the end of each topic, there are two sections that review the content of the
section (Key Topics) and prepare students for whatโs coming next (Summary and Plan of
Study).
Comments
Instructors may want to cover this chapter in several lectures or in one short lecture. But
remember, this chapter is an overview. Donโt fall into the trap of trying to cover too much
detail. There are 10 more chapters to take care of that! However, covering this chapter in
detail at the beginning may serve to motivate studentsโ interest in the topic. If students
read through the chapter without a guided lecture, they may become overwhelmed.
Chapter 12 tackles complicated concepts to give students an idea of the topics that will be
covered through the rest of the textbook.
Plan of Study
Each of the topics in this chapter concludes with a plan of study that discusses how
selected chapters in the text relate to the three broad elements presented in the
introduction: money, finance, and policy. An overview of these chapters is given below.
In the lecture notes, the plan of study for each of these topics is included in the summary.
1. Exchange rates (Chapters 13โ15)
a. Overview of the foreign exchange market (Chapter 13)
b. Theory of exchange rate behavior in the long run: The monetary approach
(Chapter 14)
c. Theory of exchange rate behavior in the short run: The asset approach
(Chapter 15)
2. Balance of payments (Chapters 16โ18)
a. Overview of balance of payments (BOP) and national income accounting
(Chapter 16)
b. The relationship between the BOP, the nationโs wealth, and living standards in
the long run (Chapter 17)
c. The relationship between the BOP, exchange rates, and the demand for output
in the short run (Chapter 18)
3. Exchange rate regimes and institutions (Chapters 19โ22)
a. Overview of fixed and floating exchange rate regimes (Chapter 19)
b. Exchange rate crisis (Chapter20)
c. The Eurozone and the theory of optimum currency areas (Chapter 21)
d. Further topics in international macroeconomics (Chapter 22)
Key Topics
Each topic and subtopic in this chapter include discussion questions that tie these broad
topics together, as well as look forward to future chapters in the text.
Lecture Notes
Three key elements (corresponding to parts 1โ3 of the chapter in organization):
โ Money: Many different currencies are used in the world today. Why? What is
their purpose? What are the implications of using so many different currencies?
โ Finance: Capital is more mobile internationallyโthe scale of international
finance is immense. Why? What is the purpose of this? Who lends/borrows? Who
benefits? What are the costs and to whom do they accrue?
โ Policy: The role of the government. How are economic policy failures
understood? What is the role of government in perpetuating/preventing these
events? What are the trade-offs?
1 Foreign Exchange: Currencies and Crises
The exchange rate is the price of a foreign currency. Therefore, when countries trade
goods and services or engage in financial transactions with each other, the exchange rate
is one of the main factors that determine the prices that will be used. When an individual
buys a product, such as a car, the components of this product may come from all over the
world. At each step of the production process, the exchange rate affects the costs of
producing this good and, therefore, the price that one pays in domestic currency.
How Exchange Rates Behave
Exchange rate regimes can be divided into two broad groups: floating and fixed. Floating
exchange rates are those that change frequently, implying that the price of one currency
changes relative to another. For example, the euroโdollar exchange rate has changed as
much as 5% within a single month. These changes are a reflection of changes in the
demand and supply of each currency in the foreign exchange market, which is studied in
the next chapter.
Fixed exchange rates are those that remain relatively constant over time, such that the
price of the currencies relative to one another is stable. For example, the yuanโdollar
exchange rate has remained relatively constant with only occasional adjustments. These
occasional adjustments are not accidental. They are the result of deliberate government
policy.
Why Exchange Rates Matter
There are two channels through which the exchange rate affects the economy: relative
prices of goods and relative prices of assets. When the exchange rate changes, this affects
the price people pay for goods imported from abroad. Similarly, changes in the exchange
rate affect the price of financial assets abroad.
For example, a change in the dollarโeuro exchange rate (the dollar price of a euro)
from $1 per euro in September 2002 to $1.25 per euro in February 2006 affected the
prices that Americans paid for European goods and the prices Europeans paid for
American goods. To see why, consider the price of a pair of leather boots that initially
cost $100 in the United States and โฌ100 in Europe during September 2002. When the
exchange rate increases to $1.25 per euro, the relative price of these boots changes.
Americans buying Italian boots have to pay $125, whereas Europeans buying American
boots pay โฌ80 ($100/$125 per euro). We can see that the increase in the dollarโeuro
exchange rate implies an increase in the price of European goods purchased by
Americans and a decrease in the price of American goods purchased by Europeans.
Therefore, the relative price of European goods to American goods increases when the
dollarโeuro exchange rate increases.
Not only consumers are affected by these changes in relative prices; producers are as
well. In the previous example, the producer of the Italian boots faces an increase in its
relative costs of manufacturing boots for export to the United States. If the Italian
manufacturer wants to avoid a decrease in sales to its U.S. market, it may choose to
continue charging $100 per pair of boots for export. However, if it hires workers and
materials in Europe, the Italian producer must continue to pay for these inputs in euros.
When it converts the $100 back into euros, the Italian producer only receives โฌ80. Thus,
the Italian producer will face a decrease in its profits. The reverse is true for American
producers exporting to Europe. They can continue charging โฌ100 per pair of boots (or
$125 converted into dollar terms), leading to an increase in profits.
Similarly, changes in exchange rates affect the relative prices of financial assets.
Suppose that you deposited $1,000 into a German checking account in September 2002.
The bank account balance would be denominated in euros. You used $1,000 to purchase
1,000 euros in September 2002, depositing that into your German checking account. If
you left the funds in this account until February 2006, you would still have โฌ1,000, but
this โฌ1,000 is now worth $1,250 because each euro is now worth $1.25. Even if the
German checking account paid no interest, you would have a 25% gain over the 53
months. A Spanish citizen depositing U.S. dollars into an American bank in September
2002 would be worse off by February 2006. An initial deposit of โฌ1,000 ($1,000 in
September 2002) would be worth only โฌ800 because each U.S. dollar was worth only 0.8
euros (1/1.25). Thus, an increase in the dollarโeuro exchange rate leads to an increase in
wealth for Americans who own Eurozone assets and a decrease in wealth for Eurozone
residents who own American assets.
When Exchange Rates Misbehave
An exchange rate crisis occurs when a country experiences a sudden and dramatic loss
in the value of its currency (a depreciation) relative to another currency following a
period of fixed or stable exchange rates. These crises are relatively common. There have
been 24 crises between 1997 and 2009.
Exchange rate crises can have significant economic consequences. The cost of
imported goods increases and the value of financial assets in the country decreases. Thus,
for a country relying heavily on direct foreign investment (FDI) and imports, a severe
economic contraction soon follows the exchange rate crisis. FDI will fall as foreign
exchange denominated profits fall, while at the same time, the merchandise trade balance
will deteriorate. Countries experiencing exchange rate crises may also be forced to
default on debt. Because of the dramatic decrease in the value of domestic foreign assets
and economic recession, the country may lack the resources to honor its debt obligations.
The economic consequences of exchange rate crises are often more severe in poorer
countries. Exchange rate crises frequently spark problems in the banking and financial
sector, among households and firms, and in government finance. In extreme cases, they
can be associated with political and social instability, as in the example of Iceland in
2008 (see Headlines: Economic Crisis in Iceland).
Often these countries seek external help from foreign allies or from international
development organizations, such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) or World
Bank. These agencies may loan the government money to mitigate the economic
consequences of an exchange rate crisis, but the costs of such loans can become
burdensome on society.
Summary and Plan of Study
In subsequent chapters, we learn about the structure and operation of the foreign
exchange market (Chapter 13). Chapters 14 and 15 present the theory of exchange rates.
Chapter 16 discusses how exchange rates affect international transactions in assets. We
examine the short-run impact of exchange rates on the demand for goods in Chapter 18,
and with this understanding, Chapter 19 examines the trade-offs governments face as
they choose between fixed and floating exchange rates. Chapter 20 covers exchange rate
crises in detail and Chapter 21 the euro, a common currency used in many countries.
2 Globalization of Finance: Debts and Deficits
Financial globalization has taken hold around the world. Competition among countries
has reduced barriers to financial flows. To understand the financial transactions among
countries, we need an accounting framework. Income, expenditure, and wealth are three
familiar measures that we will use to study how flows of goods, services, income, and
capital interact in the global macroeconomy. While this can make countries better off,
defaults and crises mean they can fall short of the potential gains.
Deficits and Surpluses: The Balance of Payments
Income refers to the amount earned by the economyโs factors of production.
Expenditure measures how much is spent on goods and services. If there is a difference
between the two, then there is either a surplus (income > expenditure) or a deficit
(expenditure > income). For international transactions, the aggregation of income and
expenditures is the current account (studied in detail in Chapter 16). If a country spends
more than its income, its current account is in deficit and it finances the difference by
borrowing from foreigners. If a country spends less than its income, the current account is
in surplus and the saving is loaned to foreigners.
Countries pay for current account deficits by borrowing from countries running
current account surpluses. For example, the U.S. has had persistent current account
deficits since 1992 (Table 12-1). These deficits have been financed by foreign purchases
of U.S. assets. When Chinaโs central bank buys U.S. Treasury securities, China is lending
to the United States. Singapore has a current account surplus, meaning its income is
larger than its expenditure. Therefore, Singapore is a lenderโit purchases foreign assets
(from the United States and other borrowers) with its surplus.
This highlights a key fact in international income accounting: as long as there are
borrowers, there also must be lenders. It is not possible for the entire world to borrow at
onceโthese resources have to come from somewhere. In fact, total global lending should
equal total global borrowing. All of these international transactions are recorded on the
balance of payments. The balance of payments must balance.
Debtors and Creditors: External Wealth
Wealth (or net worth) is equal to total assets (amount owned) less total liabilities
(amount owed). Each time a nation saves (e.g., runs a current account surplus), its total
wealth increases. When a nation runs a current account deficit, it borrows, causing a
decrease in its wealth. External wealth is equal to the total foreign assets owned less total
foreign liabilities owed.
Suppose that the United Statesโ current account is balanced, income = expenditure.
Consider a U.S. firm that seeks to borrow $500,000 to finance the expansion of its
business operations in the United States. It can issue bonds to raise these funds. When
these funds are purchased by Americans, there is no effect on the current account because
no international transaction takes place. In this transaction, both assets and liabilities in
the United States increase by the same amount, leaving wealth unaffected. However, if
foreigners purchase these bonds, then the United States experiences a decrease in its
external wealth because its liabilities increase with no corresponding increase in assets.
Therefore, the United States is able to finance an increase in spending (the $500,000 in
new capital) by borrowing from abroad.
What does this transaction mean for the current account? Note that the United States
increases expenditures by $500,000 without increasing income; therefore, the current
account goes into a deficit. What happens to external wealth? U.S. ownership of foreign
assets remains unchanged, but its foreign liabilities increase by $500,000. That is,
$500,000 is owed to the foreigners who purchased the U.S. firmโs bonds. Therefore,
external wealth is now negative.
From this example, we can see that net debtor counties such as the United States have
current account deficits associated with negative external wealth. Net creditor nations
such as Singapore have current account surpluses and positive external wealth.
There are other factors that affect external wealth. First, foreign assets can change in
value, either because the domestic prices of these assets change or because of a change in
the exchange rate. Capital gains are profits earned on assets, resulting from a change in
price. For example, if the price of a German companyโs stock increases, it generates
capital gains for people owning the stock in Germany, the United States, and elsewhere.
For the United States, this will lead to an increase in the value of foreign assets owned,
implying an increase in external wealth.
Similarly, when the value of foreign liabilities changes, this affects external wealth. If
a U.S. company goes out of business, the value of its liabilities decreases as investors
realize the company will be unlikely to pay off all of its debts and to pay profits to
stockholders. Therefore, liabilities owed by the U.S. company to foreigners decline,
causing an increase in external wealth for the United States.
Darlings and Deadbeats: Defaults and Other Risks
Since 1980, 14 countries have defaulted on their debt as a result of exchange rate crises.
Of these, fully half have defaulted twice. The preceding example provides one
explanation of why a sovereign government has an incentive to default on debt during an
exchange rate crisis. Defaulting improves its external wealth position.
There are consequences to defaulting. It makes the country far less attractive to
foreign investors. Much like a household or firm, a country will have to pay higher
interest rates to borrow following a default. Country risk refers to the additional interest
the country must pay to compensate investors for risking a default. Every countryโs debt
is compared to a benchmark risk-free interest rate, usually U.S. Treasury securities or
euro-denominated German government securities. Once a country defaults, its country
risk will increase substantially.
Summary and Plan of Study
An in-depth discussion of the balance of payments begins in Chapter 16, on national
income accounting in the open economy. That chapter explains the international
transactions described here in much more detail. Once we have established an
understanding of the accounting rules, we will develop theories of the causes and effects
of these international transactions. Chapter 18 offers a short-run model, while Chapter 19
addresses the long run. In Chapters 20 and 21, we study the role of balance of payments
in fixed versus floating exchange rate regimes, and learn why fixed exchange rate
regimes sometimes lead to exchange rate crises. These issues are explored in more detail
in Chapter 22.
3 Government and Institutions: Of Policies and Performance
We will study the role of the government in two dimensions: (1) macroeconomic policies
and regimes, and (2) institutions. Policies are designed to achieve specific
macroeconomic objectives, such as easing recessions, keeping inflation low, or
stabilizing interest rates. Policies are often made by the government. Examples of
macroeconomic policies include changes in the tax code or (in many countries) the
money supply. (In some countries, the money supply is not under the direct control of the
government. Examples include the U.S. and the European Monetary Union.) Regimes
refer to limitations on government discretionโthe rules they must follow. Available
policy and regime choices depend on the institutions the economy supports.
As examples of policies, regimes, and institutions, consider three features of the
nationโs macroeconomic environment: integration and regulation of international finance,
independence and choice of exchange rate regime, and the role of institutions.
Integration and Capital Controls: The Regulation of International Finance
Since 1970, there has been a general trend toward increased financial openness. There
has also been an increase in the volume of international financial transactions. But growth
in both areas has not been even across all countries. Consider three groups of countries
grouped according to their per capita income, economic growth, and degree of integration
into the global economy:
โ Advanced countriesโhigh levels of per capita income and well integrated into
the global economy
โ Emerging marketsโmainly middle-income countries that are growing and
becoming more integrated into the global economy
โ Developing countriesโlow-income countries that are not yet well integrated into
the global economy
The most dramatic increases in openness occurred in the early 1990s. During this
time, all three groups of countries adopted an increase in financial openness, with the
advanced economies benefiting from the largest increase in financial transactions. For
example, among advanced countries, the degree of financial openness approached 100%.
That same group saw foreign assets and liabilities rise to 5 times the GDP. Emerging and
developing countries lagged far behind in both these areas, with emerging markets only
achieving 50% financial openness and a doubling of the ratio of foreign assets and
liabilities to GDP.
Independence and Monetary Policy: The Choice of Exchange Rate Regimes
There are two broad categories of exchange rate regimes: fixed and floating. Both are
common among the countries of the world. The choice of exchange rate regime is one of
the most important decisions a government can make. On the one hand, a fixed exchange
rate eliminates the uncertainty associated with exchange rate fluctuations (exchange rate
risk). In our previous examples, we saw that a change in the exchange rate affects relative
prices, profits, and external wealth. This uncertainty could potentially limit trade and
financial transactions. However, we have also seen that fixed exchange rates can lead to
exchange rate crises that are very costly.
The use of an individual currency is often viewed as part of the national identity,
something that establishes a countryโs sovereignty. However, some groups of countries
have moved toward the adoption of a common currency. For example, as of 2009, the
Eurozone included 16 countries, each of which previously had its own currency. Other
countries have chosen to replace their own currency, using another countryโs money as
their medium of exchange. Since the U.S. dollar is often used for this purpose, the policy
is called dollarization. El Salvador and Ecuador both dollarized their economies recently.
Institutions and Economic Performance: The Quality of Governance
There are several different criteria for evaluating the quality of governance. This textbook
focuses on six: voice and accountability, political stability, government effectiveness,
regulatory quality, rule of law, and control of corruption. Better governance is strongly
associated with better economic outcomes. There is a positive relationship between good
governance and real income per person. And there is a somewhat weaker negative
correlation between good governance and the standard deviation of the rate of economic
growth. The differences are substantial, with advanced economies experiencing income
per person that is 50 times higher than the poorest developing countries. This gap in
living standards is known as The Great Divergence.
There is a negative relationship between quality institutions and income volatility.
Those countries with higher institutional quality tend to experience less volatility in
income. There are several reasons why this might be, including shifts in political power
and internal conflict.
We must confront the post hoc, ergo propter hoc fallacy here: Does the existence of
quality institutions lead to better economic outcomes? Or do good economic outcomes
make it possible to establish quality institutions? The research favors the first
explanation. Institutional quality appears to cause better economic outcomes. Given this
result, there is much debate about why poorer countries have weaker institutions.
Explanations include:
โ actions of colonizing powers (failure of colonization to establish quality
institutions)
โ differences in the evolution of legal codes that favored economic progress
โ differences in resource endowments that lead to the establishment of different
institutions according to geography
Summary and Plan of Study
The government plays an important role in several facets of the international
macroeconomy. In Chapter 13, we will see how the government participates in the
foreign exchange market. In subsequent chapters, we will see how the governmentโs
choice of exchange rate regime is related to financial openness (Chapter 15), the benefits
of financial openness (Chapter 17), the trade-offs involved in the choice of regime
(Chapter 19), and how these decisions could lead to exchange rate crises (Chapter 20).
Chapter 21 studies the institutional design of the Eurozone. A key lesson from these
chapters is that governments must acknowledge the trade-offs involved in their choices
relating to discretionary policy, choice of regime, and the decision to adopt a common
currency.
4 Conclusions
To understand the issues and debates surrounding exchange rates, the rise in international
financial transactions, and the role of institutions, we first need to understand how each
has changed over time. Then we move on to develop theories of how exchange rates and
international transactions affect the economy and the governmentโs role in this process.
Using these models helps us understand how the global macroeconomy works, what this
means for the growing gap between rich and poor countries, and how to evaluate policy
decisions.
TEACHING TIPS
Teaching Tip 1: One of the footnotes to Figure 12-5 cites M. Ayhan Kose, Eswar
Prasad, Kenneth S. Rogoff, and Shang-Jin Wei, 2006, โFinancial Globalization: A
Reappraisal,โ NBER Working Paper No. 12484. If your institution subscribes to the
NBER working paper series, you can download the paper from http://www.nber.org. If
not, the following page contains the list of countries included in each of the three major
categories: Advanced Economies, Emerging Market Economies, and Other Developing
Economies. Ask the class to study this list and discuss the countries that might have
moved to a different group since 2006. (Venezuela is one obvious example. That country
almost certainly can no longer be included in the emerging market group.)
Advanced Economies
The 21 advanced industrial economies in our sample are Australia (AUS), Austria
(AUT), Belgium (BEL), Canada (CAN), Denmark (DNK), Finland (FIN), France (FRA),
Germany (DEU), Greece (GRC), Ireland (IRL), Italy (ITA), Japan (JPN), Netherlands
(NLD), New Zealand (NZL), Norway (NOR), Portugal (PRT), Spain (ESP), Sweden
(SWE), Switzerland (CHE), United Kingdom (GBR), and the United States (USA).
Emerging Market Economies
This group includes 20 countriesโArgentina (ARG), Brazil (BRA), Chile (CHL), China
(CHN), Colombia (COL), Egypt (EGY), India (IND), Indonesia (IDN), Israel (ISR),
Korea (KOR), Malaysia (MYS), Mexico (MEX), Pakistan (PAK), Peru (PER),
Philippines (PHL), Singapore (SGP), South Africa (ZAF), Thailand (THA), Turkey
(TUR), and Venezuela (VEN).
Other Developing Economies
This group includes 30 countriesโAlgeria (DZA), Bangladesh (BGD), Bolivia (BOL),
Cameroon (CMR), Costa Rica (CRI), Dominican Republic (DOM), Ecuador (ECU), El
Salvador (SLV), Fiji (FJI), Ghana (GHA), Guatemala (GTM), Honduras (HND), Iran
(IRN), Jamaica (JAM), Kenya (KEN), Malawi (MWI), Mauritius (MUS), Nepal (NPL),
Niger (NER), Papua New Guinea (PNG), Paraguay (PRY), Senegal (SEN), Sri Lanka
(LKA), Tanzania (TZA), Togo (TGO), Trinidad and Tobago (TTO), Tunisia (TUN),
Uruguay (URY), Zambia (ZMB), and Zimbabwe (ZWE).
IN-CLASS PROBLEMS
1. Go to http://www.oanda.com and download data on the following currencies relative
to the U.S. dollar: Malaysian ringgit, British (U.K.) pound, and the Chinese yuan.
What are the exchange rates today (measured as foreign currency per U.S. dollar)?
Among these currencies, which are fixed, which are floating, and which have shifted
from fixed to floating over the past 25 years and why?
Answer: Answers will vary. The yuan is fixed to the U.S. dollar and remains so even
if the Chinese government has committed to a gradual appreciation. The ringgit
switched from free float to pegged in 1997. The British pound is a free floating
currency.
2. Two countries recently experienced exchange rate crises, but their response was
markedly different. First, Russia experienced a dramatic decrease in the value of the
Russian ruble relative to the U.S. dollar in 1998. The Russian government responded
by suspending payments on foreign debt. Similarly, South Korea experienced a
decrease in the value of the won in 1997. In contrast, South Korea did not default on
its debt. Why might these two countries have behaved differently in response to their
respective crises? What are the benefits of default? What are the drawbacks?
Answer: They behaved differently because each faces a different set of costs and
benefits associated with default. One benefit of default is that it allows a country to
improve its external wealth by decreasing its foreign liabilities. One cost of default is
added country risk, meaning the country will need to pay higher interest rates to
attract investment in the future. For Russia, the benefits of default outweighed the
costs. Looking at the map of the World Bankโs Worldwide Governance Indicator, we
see that South Korea is in the top 50% but Russia only the top 75%. Russia probably
has very little to lose by defaulting.
3. For several years, there has been substantial pressure on China from the U.S.
government to allow the value of the yuan to decrease relative to the U.S. dollar. Why
might the U.S. government want this change in the value of the yuan? How would
such a change affect the relative price of Chinese goods versus U.S. goods? How
would it affect the value of U.S. liabilities owned by Chinese residents?
Answer: A decrease in the yuanโdollar exchange rate would lead to an increase in the
relative price of Chinese goods. This would make Chinese goods exported to the
United States relatively less attractive for Americans. At the same time, it would
make U.S. imports into China more attractive for Chinese consumers. The decrease in
the yuanโdollar exchange rate would lead to a decrease in the value of U.S. liabilities
owned by Chinese residents. When Chinese residents convert their dollardenominated liabilities back into yuan, they will receive fewer yuan after the yuanโ
dollar exchange rate decreases because each dollar is now worth fewer yuan.
4. Review the data presented in Figures 12-5 and Figure 12-7. From Figure 12-5, panel
(b), what do you observe about the volume of financial transactions in developing
countries relative to those in advanced countries and emerging markets since 1990?
Drawing on the information presented in the figures mentioned above, why is this the
case? Can we attribute these patterns to financial openness or to institutions?
Answer: Developing countries have not experienced the same increase in financial
transactions observed in advanced countries and emerging markets. Based on Figure
12-5, panel (a), we see this is partially explained by financial openness. Although
openness has increased since 1970, the developing countries have not seen the same
increases in openness as was observed in advanced countries and emerging markets.
From Figure 12-7, we see that developing countries tend to have weaker institutions.
This is, in turn, associated with lower income per person and higher income volatility.
5. Consider the choice of a fixed versus a floating exchange rate regime. Is a common
currency more like a fixed or a floating exchange rate regime between the
participating countries? What is the difference between a common currency and
dollarization?
Answer: A common currency is a fixed exchange rate regime. With a common
currency, the exchange rate between countries is fixed because there is only one
currency used in both countries. However, dollarization differs from a common
currency. When a country adopts a dollarization regime, it loses an independent
monetary policy. With a common currency, there is typically joint governance of
monetary policy. Under a common currency regime, each country will at least have
some input into policy. But a country that adopts dollarization is unlikely to have
much influence with the Federal Reserve.
Introduction to Exchange Rates
and the Foreign Exchange Market
Questions to Consider
1. What features of exchange rates do we need to
understand?
2. How does the foreign exchange market operate?
3. Why do arbitrage and expectations matter for
exchange rates?
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
1
Introduction
โข Exchange rates affect large flows of international trade
by influencing the prices of goods in different currencies,
and also affect international trade in assets, via the prices
of stocks, bonds, and other investments.
โข In the foreign exchange market, trillions of dollars are
traded each day and the economic implications of shifts in
the market can be dramatic.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
2
Introduction
In this chapter, we begin to study the nature and impact of
activity in the foreign exchange market. The topics we cover
include:
โข Exchange rate basics
โข Basic facts about exchange rate behavior
โข The foreign exchange market
โข Two key market mechanisms: arbitrage and expectations
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
3
1 Exchange Rate Essentials
An exchange rate (E) is the price of some foreign currency
expressed in terms of a home (or domestic) currency.
โข Because an exchange rate is the relative price of two
currencies, it may be quoted in either of two ways:
o The number of home currency units that can be
exchanged for one unit of foreign currency
o The number of foreign currency units that can be
exchanged for one unit of home currency
โข To avoid confusion, we must specify which country is the
home country and which is foreign.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
4
1 Exchange Rate Essentials
Defining the Exchange Rate
When we refer to a particular countryโs exchange rate, we will
quote it in units of home currency per units of foreign currency.
โข For example:
o The U.S. exchange rate with Japan is quoted as U.S.
dollars per yen (or $/ยฅ).
o Denmarkโs exchange rate with the Eurozone is quoted as
Danish krone per euro (or kr/โฌ).
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
5
1 Exchange Rate Essentials
TABLE 2-1
Exchange Rate Quotations This table shows major exchange rates as they might appear in the
financial media. Columns (1) to (3) show rates on December 31, 2015. For comparison,
columns (4) to (6) show rates on December 31, 2014. For example, column (1) shows that at
the end of 2015, one U.S. dollar was worth 1.501 Canadian dollars, 6.870 Danish krone, 0.921
euros, and so on. The euroโdollar rates appear in bold type.
E$/โฌ = 1.086 = U.S. exchange rate (American terms)
Eโฌ/$ = 0.921 = Eurozone exchange rate (European terms)
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
$/โฌ
โฌ/$
6
1 Exchange Rate Essentials
Appreciations and Depreciations
โข If one currency buys more of another currency, we say it has
experienced an appreciation.
o We also might say it has risen in value, appreciated, or
strengthened against the other currency.
โข If a currency buys less of another currency, we say it has
experienced a depreciation.
o We also might say it has fallen in value, depreciated, or
weakened against the other currency.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
7
1 Exchange Rate Essentials
Appreciations and Depreciations
In U.S. terms, the following holds true:
โข When the U.S. exchange rate E$/โฌ rises, more dollars are
needed to buy one euro. The price of one euro goes up in
dollar terms, and the U.S. dollar experiences a depreciation.
It has fallen in value or weakened against the euro.
โข When the U.S. exchange rate E$/โฌ falls, fewer dollars are
needed to buy one euro. The price of one euro goes down in
dollar terms, and the U.S. dollar experiences an appreciation.
It has risen in value or strengthened against the euro.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
8
1 Exchange Rate Essentials
Appreciations and Depreciations
To determine the size of an appreciation or depreciation, we
compute the proportional change, as follows:
โข In 2014, at time t, the dollar value of the euro was
E$/โฌ,t = $1.211.
โข
In 2015, at time t + 1, the dollar value of the euro was
E$/โฌ,t+1 = $1.086.
โข The change in the dollar value of the euro was
ฮ E$/โฌ,t = 1.086 โ 1.211 = โ$0.125.
โข The percentage change was
ฮ E$/โฌ,t/E$/โฌ,t = โ0.125/1.211 = โ10.32%.
โข Thus, the dollar appreciated against the euro by 10.32%.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
9
1 Exchange Rate Essentials
Appreciations and Depreciations
Similarly, over the same year:
โข In 2014, at time t, the euro value of the dollar was
Eโฌ /$,t = โฌ0.826.
โข
In 2015, at time t + 1, the euro value of the dollar was
Eโฌ /$,t+1 = โฌ0.921.
โข The change in the dollar value of the euro was
ฮEโฌ /$,t = 0.921 โ 0.826 = +โฌ0.095.
โข The percentage change was
ฮEโฌ/$,t / Eโฌ/$,t = +0.095/0.826 = +11.50%.
โข Thus, the euro depreciated against the dollar by 11.50%.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
10
1 Exchange Rate Essentials
Multilateral Exchange Rates
Economists calculate multilateral exchange rate changes by
aggregating bilateral exchange rates using trade weights to construct
an average over each currency in the basket. The resulting measure
is called the change in the effective exchange rate. For example:
โข Suppose 40% of Home trade is with country 1 and 60% is with
country 2. Homeโs currency appreciates 10% against 1 but
depreciates 30% against 2.
โข To find the change in Homeโs effective exchange rate, multiply
each exchange rate change by the trade share and sum:
(โ10% โข 40%) + (30% โข 60%) = (โ0.1 โข 0.4) + (0.3 โข 0.6) =
โ0.04 + 0.18 = 0.14 = +14%.
โข Homeโs effective exchange rate has depreciated by 14%.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
11
1 Exchange Rate Essentials
Multilateral Exchange Rates
In general, suppose there are N currencies in the basket, and
Homeโs trade with all N partners is:
Trade = Trade1 + Trade2 + . . . + TradeN.
Applying trade weights to each bilateral exchange rate change,
the home countryโs effective exchange rate (Eeffective) will change
according to the following weighted average:
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
12
1 Exchange Rate Essentials
Multilateral Exchange Rates
FIGURE 2-1
Effective Exchange Rates: Change in the Value of the U.S. Dollar, 2002โ2015 The chart shows the
value of the dollar using two different baskets of foreign currencies. Against a basket of 7 major
currencies, the dollar had depreciated by 35% by early 2008. Against a broad basket of 26 currencies,
the dollar had lost only 25% by 2008. This is because the dollar was floating against the major
currencies, but the broad basket included important U.S. trading partners (such as China) that
maintained fixed or tightly managed exchange rates against the dollar. These trends only briefly
reversed during the global financial crisis of 2008 before continuing up to 2015.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
13
1 Exchange Rate Essentials
Example: Using Exchange Rates to Compare Prices
in a Common Currency
TABLE 2-2
Using the Exchange Rate to Compare Prices in a Common Currency Now pay
attention, 007! This table shows how the hypothetical cost of James Bondโs next
tuxedo in different locations depends on the exchange rates that prevail.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
14
2 Exchange Rates in Practice
Exchange Rate Regimes: Fixed Versus Floating
There are two major types of exchange rate regimesโ
fixed and floating:
โข A fixed (or pegged) exchange rate fluctuates in a narrow
range (or not at all) against some base currency over a
sustained period. The exchange rate can remain fixed for long
periods only if the government intervenes in the foreign
exchange market in one or both countries.
โข A floating (or flexible) exchange rate fluctuates in a wider
range, and the government makes no attempt to fix it against
any base currency. Appreciations and depreciations may
occur yearly, monthly, by the day, or even every minute.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
15
APPLICATION
FIGURE 2-2 (1 of 2)
Exchange Rate Behavior: Selected Developed Countries, 1996โ2015
This figure shows the exchange rates of three currencies against the U.S. dollar. The U.S.
dollar is in a floating relationship with the yen, the pound, and the Canadian dollar (or
loonie). The U.S. dollar is subject to a great deal of volatility because it is in a floating
regime, or free float.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
16
APPLICATION
FIGURE 2-2 (2 of 2)
Exchange Rate Behavior: Selected Developed Countries, 1996โ2015 (cont.)
This figure shows exchange rates of three currencies against the euro, which was
introduced in 1999. The pound and the yen float against the euro. The Danish krone
provides an example of a fixed exchange rate. There is only a tiny variation around this
rate, no more than plus or minus 2%. This type of fixed regime is known as a band.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
17
APPLICATION
FIGURE 2-3 (1 of 2)
Exchange Rate Behavior: Selected Developing Countries, 1996โ2015
Selected Developing Countries, 1996โ2015 Exchange rates in developing countries show
a wide variety of experiences and greater volatility. Pegging is common but is punctuated
by periodic crises (you can see the effects of these crises in graphs for Thailand, South
Korea, and India).
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
18
APPLICATION
FIGURE 2-3 (2 of 2)
Exchange Rate Behavior: Selected Developing Countries, 1996โ2015 (cont.)
India is an example of a middle ground, somewhere between a fixed rate and a free float,
called a managed float. Colombia is an example of a crawling peg. The Colombian peso
is allowed to crawl gradually, and it steadily depreciated at an almost constant rate for
several years from 1996 to 2002. Dollarization occurred in Ecuador in 2000, a process
that occurs when a country unilaterally adopts the currency of another country.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
19
APPLICATION
Recent Exchange Rate Experiences
Exchange Rate Regimes of the World
โข Figure 2-4 shows an IMF classification of exchange rate
regimes around the world, which allows us to see the
prevalence of different regime types across the whole
spectrum, from fixed to floating.
โข The classification covers 182 economies for the year 2010,
and regimes are ordered from the most rigidly fixed to the
most freely floating.
โข Six of these countries have a currency board, a type of
fixed regime that has special legal and procedural rules
designed to make the peg โharderโโthat is, more durable.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
20
APPLICATION
FIGURE 2-4
A Spectrum of Exchange Rate Regimes
This figure shows IMF classification of exchange rate regimes around the world for 182
economies in 2010. Regimes are ordered from the most rigidly fixed to the most freely floating.
Six countries use an ultra-hard peg called a currency board, while 35 others have a hard peg.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
21
APPLICATION
FIGURE 2-4)
A Spectrum of Exchange Rate Regimes (continued)
An additional 43 counties have bands, crawling pegs, or crawling bands, while 46
countries have exchange rates that either float freely, are managed floats, or are allowed to
float within wide bands.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
22
3 The Market for Foreign Exchange
Exchange rates the world over are set in the foreign exchange
market (or forex or FX market).
โข The forex market is not an organized exchange: Trade is
conducted โover the counter.โ
โข In January 2013, the global forex market traded $5.3 trillion
per day in currency.
โข The three major foreign exchange centers are located in the
United Kingdom, the United States, and Japan.
โข Other important centers for forex trade include Hong Kong,
Paris, Singapore, Sydney, and Zurich.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
23
3 The Market for Foreign Exchange
The Spot Contract
โข The simplest forex transaction is a contract for the immediate
exchange of one currency for another between two parties.
This is known as a spot contract.
โข The exchange rate for this transaction is often called the spot
exchange rate.
โข The use of the term โexchange rateโ always refers to the spot
rate for our purposes.
โข The spot contract is the most common type of trade and
appears in almost 90% of all forex transactions.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
24
3 The Market for Foreign Exchange
Derivatives
โข In addition to the spot contracts
other forex contracts include
forwards, swaps, futures, and
options.
FIGURE 2-5
โข Collectively, all these related
forex contracts are termed
derivatives.
โข The spot and forward rates
closely track each other.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
25
APPLICATION
Foreign Exchange Derivatives
Forwards
A forward contract differs from a spot contract in that the two
parties make the contract today, but the settlement date for the
delivery of the currencies is in the future, or forward. The time to
delivery, or maturity, varies. However, because the price is fixed
as of today, the contract carries no risk.
Swaps
A swap contract combines a spot sale of foreign currency with a
forward repurchase of the same currency. This is a common
contract for counterparties dealing in the same currency pair over
and over again. Combining two transactions reduces
transactions costs.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
26
APPLICATION
Foreign Exchange Derivatives
Futures
A futures contract is a promise that the two parties holding the
contract will deliver currencies to each other at some future date
at a prespecified exchange rate, just like a forward contract.
Unlike the forward contract, futures contracts are standardized,
mature at certain regular dates, and can be traded on an organized
futures exchange.
Options
An option provides one party, the buyer, with the right to buy
(call) or sell (put) a currency in exchange for another at a
prespecified exchange rate at a future date. The buyer is under no
obligation to trade and will not exercise the option if the spot
price on the expiration date turns out to be more favorable.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
27
APPLICATION
Foreign Exchange Derivatives
Derivatives allow investors to engage in hedging (risk avoidance)
and speculation (risk taking).
โข Example 1: Hedging. As chief financial officer of a U.S. firm,
you expect to receive payment of โฌ1 million in 90 days for
exports to France. The current spot rate is $1.20 per euro. Your
firm will incur losses on the deal if the euro weakens to less
than $1.10 per euro. You advise that the firm buy โฌ1 million in
call options on dollars at a rate of $1.15 per euro, ensuring that
the firmโs euro receipts will sell for at least this rate. This
locks in a minimal profit even if the spot rate falls below
$1.15. This is hedging.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
28
APPLICATION
Foreign Exchange Derivatives
Derivatives allow investors to engage in hedging (risk avoidance)
and speculation (risk taking).
โข Example 2: Speculation. The market currently prices one-year
euro futures at $1.30, but you think the dollar will weaken to
$1.43 in the next 12 months. If you wish to make a bet, you
would buy these futures, and if you are proved right, you will
realize a 10% profit. Any level above $1.30 will generate a
profit. If the dollar is at or below $1.30 a year from now,
however, your investment in futures will be a total loss. This is
speculation.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
29
3 The Market for Foreign Exchange
Private Actors
โข Most forex traders work for commercial banks. About 75% of
all forex transactions globally are handled by just 10 banks.
โข The exchange rates for these trades underlie quoted market
exchange rates.
โข Some corporations may trade in the market if they are engaged
in extensive transactions in foreign markets.
Government Actions
โข Some governments engage in policies that restrict trading,
movement of forex, or cross-border financial transactions. These
are called a form of capital control.
โข In lieu of capital controls, the central bank must stand ready to
buy or sell its own currency to maintain a fixed exchange rate.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
30
4 Arbitrage and Spot Exchange Rates
FIGURE 2-6
Arbitrage and Spot Rates Arbitrage ensures that the trade of currencies in New York
along the path AB occurs at the same exchange rate as via London along path ACDB.
At B the pounds received must be the same, regardless of the route taken to get to B:
. .
ยฃ/$
ยฃ/$
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
31
4 Arbitrage and Spot Exchange Rates
Arbitrage with Three Currencies
In general, three outcomes are again possible.
1. The direct trade from dollars to pounds has a better rate: Eยฃ/$ >
Eยฃ/โฌ Eโฌ/$
2. The indirect trade has a better rate: Eยฃ/$ < Eยฃ/โฌ Eโฌ/$
3. The two trades have the same rate and yield the same result: Eยฃ/$ =
Eยฃ/โฌ Eโฌ/$. Only in the last case are there no profit opportunities. This is
the no-arbitrage condition:
The right-hand expression, a ratio of two exchange rates, is called a
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
cross rate.
32
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
4 Arbitrage and Spot Exchange Rates
FIGURE 2-7
Arbitrage and Cross Rates Triangular arbitrage ensures that the direct trade of currencies
along the path AB occurs at the same exchange rate as via a third currency along path
ACB. The pounds received at B must be the same on both paths:
ยฃ/$
ยฃ/โฌ โฌ/$
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
33
4 Arbitrage and Spot Exchange Rates
Cross Rates and Vehicle Currencies
โข The majority of the worldโs currencies trade directly with only
one or two of the major currencies, such as the dollar, euro,
yen, or pound.
โข Many countries do a lot of business in major currencies such as
the U.S. dollar, so individuals always have the option to engage
in a triangular trade at the cross rate.
โข When a third currency, such as the U.S. dollar, is used in these
transactions, it is called a vehicle currency because it is not the
home currency of either of the parties involved in the trade and
is just used for intermediation.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
34
5 Arbitrage and Interest Rates
An important question for investors is in which currency they
should hold their liquid cash balances.
โข Would selling euro deposits and buying dollar deposits make a
profit for a banker?
โข These decisions drive demand for dollars versus euros and the
exchange rate between the two currencies.
The Problem of Risk
A trader in New York cares about returns in U.S. dollars. A dollar
deposit pays a known return, in dollars. But a euro deposit pays a
return in euros, and one year from now we cannot know for sure
what the dollarโeuro exchange rate will be.
โข Riskless arbitrage and risky arbitrage lead to two important
implications, called parity conditions.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
35
5 Arbitrage and Interest Rates
Riskless Arbitrage: Covered Interest Parity
Contracts to exchange euros for dollars in one yearโs time carry
an exchange rate of F$/โฌ dollars per euro. This is known as the
forward exchange rate.
โข If you invest in a dollar deposit, your $1 placed in a U.S. bank
account will be worth (1 + i$) dollars in one yearโs time. The
dollar value of principal and interest for the U.S. dollar bank
deposit is called the dollar return.
โข If you invest in a euro deposit, you first need to convert the
dollar to euros. Using the spot exchange rate, $1 buys 1/E$/โฌ
euros today.
โข These 1/E$/โฌ euros would be placed in a euro account earning
iโฌ, so in a yearโs time they would be worth (1 + iโฌ)/E$/โฌ euros.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
36
5 Arbitrage and Interest Rates
Riskless Arbitrage: Covered Interest Parity
To avoid that risk, you engage in a forward contract today to
make the future transaction at a forward rate F$/โฌ.
โข The (1 + iโฌ)/E$/โฌ euros you will have in one yearโs time can
then be exchanged for (1 + iโฌ)F$/โฌ/E$/โฌ dollars, or the dollar
return on the euro bank deposit.
$/โฌ
$/โฌ
โข This is called covered interest parity (CIP) because all
exchange rate risk on the euro side has been โcoveredโ by use
of the forward contract.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
37
5 Arbitrage and Interest Rates
FIGURE 2-8
Arbitrage and Covered Interest Parity Under CIP, returns to holding dollar deposits
accruing interest going along the path AB must equal the returns from investing in euros
going along the path ACDB with risk removed by use of a forward contract. Hence, at B,
the riskless payoff must be the same on both paths:
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
38
APPLICATION
Evidence on Covered Interests Parity
FIGURE 2-9 (1 of 2)
Financial Liberalization and Covered Interest Parity
Financial Liberalization and Covered Interest Parity: Arbitrage Between the United Kingdom
and Germany The chart shows the difference in monthly pound returns on deposits in British
pounds and German marks using forward cover from 1970 to 1995. In the 1970s, the difference
was positive and often large: Traders would have profited from arbitrage by moving money
from pound deposits to mark deposits, but capital controls prevented them from freely doing so.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
39
APPLICATION
Evidence on Covered Interest Parity
FIGURE 2-9 (2 of 2)
Financial Liberalization and Covered Interest Parity (continued)
After financial liberalization, these profits essentially vanished, and no arbitrage opportunities
remained. The CIP condition held, aside from small deviations resulting from transactions costs
and measurement errors.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
40
5 Arbitrage and Interest Rates
Risky Arbitrage: Uncovered Interest Parity
โข In this case, traders face exchange rate risk and must make a
forecast of the future spot rate. We refer to the forecast as
$/โฌ , which we call the expected exchange rate.
โข Based on the forecast, you expect that the
โฌ
$/โฌ euros you
will have in one yearโs time will be worth
โฌ
$/โฌ
$/โฌ
when converted into dollars; this is the expected dollar return
on euro deposits.
โข The expression for uncovered interest parity (UIP) is:
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
41
5 Arbitrage and Interest Rates
FIGURE 2-10
Arbitrage and Uncovered Interest Parity Under CIP, returns to holding dollar deposits
accruing interest going along the path AB must equal returns from investing in euros going
along the risky path ACDB. Hence, at B, the expected payoff must be the same on both
paths:
$
$/โฌ
$/โฌ
โฌ
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
42
5 Arbitrage and Interest Rates
Risky Arbitrage : Uncovered Interest Parity
What Determines the Spot Rate?
โข Uncovered interest parity is a no-arbitrage condition that
describes an equilibrium in which investors are indifferent
between the returns on unhedged interest-bearing bank deposits
in two currencies.
โข We can rearrange the terms in the uncovered interest parity
expression to solve for the spot rate:
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
43
Assets and Their Attributes
โข An investorโs entire portfolio of assets may include stocks, bonds,
real estate, art, bank deposits in various currencies, and so on. All
assets have three key attributes that influence demand: return,
risk, and liquidity.
โข An assetโs rate of return is the total net increase in wealth
resulting from holding the asset for a specified period of time,
typically one year.
โข The risk of an asset refers to the volatility of its rate of return.
โข The liquidity of an asset refers to the ease and speed with which it
can be liquidated, or sold.
โข We refer to the forecast of the rate of return as the expected rate
of return.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
44
APPLICATION
Evidence on Uncovered Interest Parity
โข Dividing the UIP by the CIP, we obtain
$/โฌ
$/โฌ
, or
โข Although the expected future spot rate and the forward rate
are used in two different forms of arbitrageโrisky and
riskless, in equilibrium they should be exactly the same!
โข If both covered interest parity and uncovered interest parity
hold, the forward must equal the expected future spot rate.
โข Risk-neutral investors have no reason to prefer to avoid risk
by using the forward rate versus embracing risk by awaiting
the future spot rate.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
45
APPLICATION
Evidence on Uncovered Interest Parity
โข If the forward rate equals the expected spot rate, the expected
rate of depreciation equals the forward premium (the
proportional difference between the forward and spot rates):
โข While the left-hand side is easily observed, the expectations
on the right-hand side are typically unobserved.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
46
APPLICATION
Evidence on Uncovered Interest Parity
FIGURE 2-11
Evidence on Interest Parity
When UIP and CIP hold, the
12-month forward premium
should equal the 12-month
expected rate of depreciation.
A scatterplot showing these
two variables should be close
to the diagonal 45-degree
line.
Using evidence from surveys
of individual forex tradersโ
expectations over the period
1988 to 1993, UIP finds some
support, as the line of best fit
is close to the diagonal.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
47
5 Arbitrage and Interest Rates
Uncovered Interest Parity: A Useful Approximation
$
โฌ
$/โฌ
$/โฌ
โข This approximate equation for UIP says that the home interest
rate equals the foreign interest rate plus the expected rate of
depreciation of the home currency.
โข Suppose the dollar interest rate is 4% per year and the euro 3%.
If UIP is to hold, the expected rate of dollar depreciation over a
year must be 1%. The total dollar return on the euro deposit is
approximately equal to the 4% that is offered by dollar deposits.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
48
5 Arbitrage and Interest Rates
Summary
FIGURE 2-12
How Interest Parity
Relationships Explain Spot and
Forward Rates In the spot
market, UIP provides a model
of how the spot exchange rate
is determined. To use UIP to
find the spot rate, we need to
know the expected future spot
rate and the prevailing interest
rates for the two currencies. In
the forward market, CIP
provides a model of how the
forward exchange rate is
determined. When we use CIP,
we derive the forward rate from
the current spot rate (from UIP)
and the interest rates for the
two currencies.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
49
KEY POINTS
1. The exchange rate in a country is the price of a unit of
foreign currency expressed in terms of the home currency.
This price is determined in the spot market for foreign
exchange.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
50
KEY POINTS
2. When the home exchange rate rises, less foreign currency is
bought/sold per unit of home currency; the home currency
has depreciated. If home currency buys x% less foreign
currency, the home currency is said to have depreciated by
x%.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
51
KEY POINTS
3. When the home exchange rate falls, more foreign currency is
bought/sold per unit of home currency; the home currency
has appreciated. If home currency buys x% more foreign
currency, the home currency is said to have appreciated by
x%.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
52
KEY POINTS
4. The exchange rate is used to convert the prices of goods and
assets into a common currency to allow meaningful price
comparisons.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
53
KEY POINTS
5. Exchange rates may be stable over time or they may
fluctuate. History supplies examples of the former (fixed
exchange rate regimes) and the latter (floating exchange rate
regimes) as well as a number of intermediate regime types.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
54
KEY POINTS
6. An exchange rate crisis occurs when the exchange rate
experiences a sudden and large depreciation. These events
are often associated with broader economic and political
turmoil, especially in developing countries.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
55
KEY POINTS
7. Some countries may forgo a national currency to form a
currency union with other nations (e.g., the Eurozone), or
they may unilaterally adopt the currency of another country
(โdollarizationโ).
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
56
KEY POINTS
8. Looking across all countries today, numerous fixed and
floating rate regimes are observed, so we must understand
both types of regime.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
57
KEY POINTS
9. The forex market is dominated by spot transactions, but
many derivative contracts exist, such as forwards, swaps,
futures, and options.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
58
KEY POINTS
10. The main actors in the market are private investors and
(frequently) government authorities, usually represented by
the central bank.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
59
KEY POINTS
11. Arbitrage on currencies means that spot exchange rates are
approximately equal in different forex markets. Cross rates
(for indirect trades) and spot rates (for direct trades) are also
approximately equal.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
60
KEY POINTS
12. Riskless interest arbitrage leads to the covered interest parity
(CIP) condition. CIP says that the dollar return on dollar
deposits must equal the dollar return on euro deposits, where
forward contracts are used to cover exchange rate risk.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
61
KEY POINTS
13. Covered interest parity says that the forward rate is
determined by home and foreign interest rates and the spot
exchange rate.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
62
KEY POINTS
14. Risky interest arbitrage leads to the uncovered interest parity
(UIP) condition. UIP says that when spot contracts are used
and exchange rate risk is not covered, the dollar return on
dollar deposits must equal the expected dollar returns on
euro deposits.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
63
KEY POINTS
15. Uncovered interest parity explains how the spot rate is
determined by the home and foreign interest rates and the
expected future spot exchange rate.
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
Economics, 4e | Feenstra/Taylor
64
International Macroeconomics 4th Edition Feenstra Solutions Manual
Full Download: https://testbanklive.com/download/international-macroeconomics-4th-edition-feenstra-solutions-manual/
KEY TERMS
exchange rate
appreciation
depreciation
effective exchange rate
exchange rate regimes
fixed (or pegged) exchange
rates
floating (or flexible) exchange
rates
free float exchange rate regime
band
managed float
exchange rate crises
crawling peg
currency (or monetary) union
dollarization
currency board
foreign exchange (forex or FX)
market
spot contract
spot exchange rate
spread
market friction
transaction costs
derivatives
forward
swap
futures
option
commercial banks
interbank trading
corporations
nonbank financial
institutions
capital control
official market
black market
intervention
ยฉ 2017 Worth Publishers International
4e Bank
| Feenstra/Taylor
Full download all chapters instantly please go to SolutionsEconomics,
Manual, Test
site: testbanklive.com
arbitrage
equilibrium
no-arbitrage condition
cross rate
vehicle currency
forward exchange rate
covered interest parity (CIP)
rate of return
risk
liquidity
expected rate of return
expected exchange rate
uncovered interest parity
(UIP)
expected rate of
depreciation
forward premium
65
Document Preview (93 of 714 Pages)
User generated content is uploaded by users for the purposes of learning and should be used following SchloarOn's honor code & terms of service.
You are viewing preview pages of the document. Purchase to get full access instantly.
-37%
Solution Manual for International Macroeconomics, 4th Edition
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
24/7 Live Chat
Instant Download
100% Confidential
Store
Sophia Williams
0 (0 Reviews)
Best Selling
Data Structures and Other Objects Using C++ 4th Edition Solution Manual
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
Test Bank for Hospitality Facilities Management and Design, 4th Edition
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
Solution Manual for Designing the User Interface: Strategies for Effective Human-Computer Interaction, 6th Edition
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
Chemistry: Principles And Reactions, 7th Edition Test Bank
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
2023-2024 ATI Pediatrics Proctored Exam with Answers (139 Solved Questions)
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
The World Of Customer Service, 3rd Edition Test Bank
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)